Jim Whitney Economics 357

    V. Tort law
    D. Liability

    2. Victim fault

    b. Economic analysis of legal options (cont'd.)

    Conduct under alternative legal rules: see handout (cont'd.)
    Result:
All negligence rules yield the same incentive: neither side is negligent, "provided that the law defines due care--as it does--as the care that is optimal if the other party is exercising due care." (P173)

    Since efficiency is not enhanced by making the negligent injurer pay damages to the negligent victim, the common law traditionally allowed the cost of the accident to lie where it fell, in order to minimize the costs of administering the legal system. (P174)
    =>
contributory negligence --> fewer cases

    Comparative negligence entails a transfer payment that generates no allocative gain and transfer payments involve administrative costs. (P174-5)
    This requires the expenditure of additional resources by the parties and the courts, and by making it harder to predict the extent of liability may increase the rate of litigation. (P175)
    Both contributory negligence and comparative negligence --> uncertain legal outcomes and uncertain effects on the amount of care taken by injurers and victims (P175)
   
Comparative negligence makes most economic sense when society wants to use the tort system to provide insurance to accident victims, because it gives the careless victim of a careless injurer something; contributory negligence gives him nothing.
    But why in an age of much more widely available market insurance than when contributory negligence held sway in tort law there should be a desire to provide insurance through the tort system is a mystery to the positive economic theorist of the common law. (P175)


 

    b. Assumption of risk

    Ordway (d) v. Superior Court / Casella (p) 198 Cal.App.3d 98 (1988)
    Appeal to Superior Court for dismissal of case

  1. P: Why did you file this case?
  2. D: Why do you think you shouldn't be held liable?
  3. P: Do you consider anything you did to constitute contributory negligence?
  4. D: Why do you still think you should not be liable?
  5. D: Any other points you would like to raise?
  6. P: Any final arguments?
  7. Others: Is defendant liable?
  8. D: You appealed to have this case dismissed--was it?
  9. P: Would you have a better case if you had not been paid as a jockey?
  10. D: What care do you owe to participants?

    illustrates assumption of risk --> no liability

    "The defenses of assumption of risk and contributory negligence are based on different theories. Contributory negligence arises from a [plaintiff's] lack of due care. The defense of assumption of risk, on the other hand, will negative liability regardless of the fact that plaintiff may have acted with due care.
    "Or stated another way, the individual who knowingly and voluntarily assumes a risk, whether for recreational enjoyment, economic reward, or some similar purpose, is deemed to have agreed to reduce the defendant's duty of care. ... The defendant must, however, anticipate that some risks will be unreasonably undertaken, and a failure to guard against those may result in liability.

    "The correct rule is this: If the defendant's actions, even those which might cause incidental physical damage in some sports, are within the ordinary expectations of the participants -- such as blocking in football, checking in hockey, knock-out punches in boxing, and aggressive riding in horse racing -- no cause of action can succeed based on a resulting injury."

    assumption of risk => no liability => victim has incentives to take all cost-effective precautions, observable and unobservable. Logical in cases of hazardous activities.


 

    3. Strict liability

    Strict tort liability means that someone who causes an accident is liable for the victim's damages even if the injury could not have been avoided by the exercise of due care. (P177)

    Turner v Big Lake Oil Company, 128 Tex. 155; 96 S.W.2d 221 (1936)

  1. P: Why did you file this case?
  2. D: Why do you think you shouldn't be held liable?
  3. P: You appeal to Rylands v. Fletcher (1868) for support. How does that case help bolster yours?
  4. D: How do you respond to plaintiff's reliance on Rylands v. Fletcher?
  5. D: Any other points you would like to raise?
  6. P: Any final arguments?
  7. Others: Is defendant liable?
  8. D: Were you held liable?

    contrasts strict ("absolute") liability versus negligence
    opts for negligence--strict liability is not a default standard in the common law
    with a high bar at that--requires that plaintiffs "prove some specific act of neglect" by defendant rather than even a "res ipsa loquitor" argument

    So the issue becomes, when does the law enforce a standard of strict liability?


 

    Escola v. Coca Cola Bottling Co., 24 Cal. 2d 453 (1944)

  1. What are the facts of the case?
  2. Did the plaintiff provide evidence of any specific act of negligence?
  3. What doctrine did plaintiff rely on to argue for damages?
  4. How long had the bottles been sitting out before being put in the refrigerator? (per Friedman: perhaps summer & in Fresno)
  5. Why might that matter?
  6. Did the plaintiff receive damages?
  7. What sort of argument does Judge Traynor make in the concurring opinion?
  8. What has a non-negligent manufacturer done to be liable nonetheless, according to Traynor?
  9. According to Traynor, how will firms pay for the cost of strict liability?
  10. Why does Traynor feel that the case for strict liability has grown stronger over time?

    discusses strict liability
    the most interesting part of the case is the concurring opinion
    "The liability of the manufacturer to an immediate buyer injured by a defective product follows without proof of negligence from the implied warranty of safety attending the sale."
    "It is evident that the manufacturer can anticipate some hazards and guard against the recurrence of others, as the public cannot.
    "It is to the public interest to discourage the marketing of products having defects that are a menace to the public. If such products nevertheless find their way into the market it is to the public interest to place the responsibility for whatever injury they may cause upon the manufacturer, who, even if he is not negligent in the manufacture of the product, is responsible for its reaching the market."


 

    the issue: Do we follow a rule of caveat emptor (let the buyer beware), under which the buyer takes the good as he finds it, complete with any defects, or a rule of caveat venditor, under which, if anything goes wrong, the seller is laible? (F213)

    advantage to caveat emptor: avoids lawsuits
    advantage to caveat venditor: sellers may be low-cost avoiders of damage

    assign liability to the side with better information (F215)
    Better seller information
    => apply caveat venditor
    => seller insures product.
(F214)

    encourages sellers to exploit all safeguards, observable and unobservable
    [because of undercompensation for loss in practice] even with tort rules that make someone else liable, most of us still have at least some incentive to avoid being victims [a form of coinsurance] (F215)

    In general, true insurance is preferable to tort insurance:
    Insurance policies have two important advantages over liability law as mechanism for protecting people from risk. The first is that liability law is too selective.... A second advantage ... is that an insurance company wants a reputation for being generous out benefits.... (F215)

    Even with caveat emptor: parties can still assign liability by contract, rather than tort law (F216)


 

    McDaniel v. McNeil Lab. Inc., 241 N.W.2d 822 (1976)

  1. P: Why did you file this case?
  2. D: Why do you think you shouldn't be held liable?
  3. P: Did you introduce evidence that Innovar was of unsafe design?
  4. D: How do you respond to that evidence?
  5. D: Any other points you would like to raise?
  6. P: Any final arguments?
  7. Others: Is defendant liable?
  8. P: Was defendant held liable?
  9. D: Does government approval guarantee lack of liability?

    illustrates that "product liability" is not true strict liability
    defendants can escape liability if there is no defect