III. Property
D. Conflicting property rights
1. Incompatible uses
b. In practice (cont'd.)
Boomer v.
Atlantic Cement Co. 26 N.Y.2d 219 (1970)
What are the facts of the
case?
Illustrates easement with liability for damages
Raises the contrast between temporary and permanent damages
Expresses a preference for legislative policy for handling pollution
Spur Industries v. Del E. Webb Development (1972)
Illustrates injunction with liability for damages
Illustrates the reciprocal nature of incentives to internalize externalities
Legal costs include costs of (1) getting information and (2) court errors
There is no perfect/universal set of rules--all rules face tradeoffs
Choosing rules: | Legal costs | ||
High | Low | ||
Transaction costs | High | Pigouvian approach | Liability right: damages |
Low | Property right: injunction/easement |
(1) Low transaction costs favor property right remedies--injunction/easement
For private parties: Property
and liability rights both --> efficient outcome
For the courts: property rights are cheaper to administer
Ex: difficult to determine damages when Windsong satellite
strays into Orbitcom's satellite orbit. (CU105)
"Bright line" rules:
predictable and cheap
"General rules that yield easily predictable results are
sometimes referred to bright line rules (to reduce uncertainty and rent seeking);
rules that require a case-by-case decision by the courts are referred to as standards. (F41)
(2) High
transaction costs relative to legal costs favor damage remedies
"Private bargaining is
unlikely to succeed in disputes involving a large number of geographically dispersed
people because communication costs are high, monitoring is costly, and strategic behavior
is likely to occur. . . . In these cases, damages are the preferred remedy." (CU106)
Calabresi, Guido, and A. Douglas Melamed. "Property rules,
liability rules, and inalienability: One view of the cathedral." Harvard Law Review
85 (1972): 1089. (CU105)
When there are free-rider problems (holdout or false valuations),
"an argument can readily be made for moving from a property rule to a liability rule.
If society can remove from the market the valuation of each tract of land, decide the
value collectively, and impose it, then the holdout problem is gone. Similarly, if society
can value collectively each individual citizen's desire to have a park and charge him a
'benefits' tax based upon it, the freeloader problem is gone." (LEA195)
High transaction costs are
commonplace
Especially with large stakes: Ex: Boomer v.
Atlantic Cement:
cost to plaintiff = 185K; injunction cost to cement firm= 45M =>
much room to negotiate and bluff.
"This expensive bargaining was avoided by the court's novel
remedial approach, although a simple alternative would have been, by a balancing of the
costs to the respective parties, to have found that the plant was not a nuisance."
(P71)
And even in small-number cases
Fountainebleau Hotel Corp. v. Forty-Five Twenty-Five, Inc. 114
So.2d 357 (1959) <-- "spite"
and bilateral monopoly
(2.1) Permanent or temporary damages?
Permanent in Boomer v. Atlantic Cement Co. 26 N.Y.2d 219 (1970)
Advantage to permanent damages:
eliminates future litigation costs
Advantage to temporary damages: preserves incentive to innovate (Ex: pointed out in the dissent in Boomer v. Atlantic Cement Co.
"[T]emporary damages tend to be more
efficient given easily measured damages and rapid innovation. Conversely, permanent
damages tend to be more efficient given costly measurement of damages and slow
innovation." (CU170)
Example: easements for overflights
easements for overflights are hard because of incentives
from alternative options (holdouts with easement purchases; no incentive to abate after
eminent domain, etc.) (P63)
(2.2) Actual or mitigated damages?
mitigated damages: damages remaining
after cost-effective steps to avoid damages
the core of the critique by Coase--these get overlooked in Pigouvian
approach
MB polluter = train
emitting sparks MC pollutee = farm with wheat MC' = farm with clover |
![]() |
![]() |
Advantage to actual damages: lower
information costs
but no incentive to reduce costs--why switch to
clover w/ 100% damages paid?
Advantage to mitigated damages: provides an incentive to reduce costs
Ex: Friedman -- base damages on clover, not wheat.
Ex: Spur Industries v. Del E. Webb Development
(1972)
Entitlement to shutdown or relocation costs reduces optimal location
incentives (P63)
(3) High transaction costs and legal costs favor Pigouvian approach
There is still a major role for the Pigouvian
approach.
Many of our most substantial externality problems are not litigated,
they are legislated.
Ex: court recognized this in Boomer v. Atlantic Cement
Note 1: a liability right provides an incentive to report the tort.
liability right = a Pigouvian tax +
compensation + incentive for private enforcement.
Note 2: with low transaction costs, Pigouvian approach can lead to too
much abatement, since failure to compensate leaves room for side bargains.
2. Takings
commonly known as eminent domain
Conflicting property rights dispute now is typically between a private and public party rather 2 private parties
a. basic analysis
U.S. Constitution, 5th amendment: "nor shall private property be taken for public use, without just compensation." (CU174)
(i) "private property" = a particular piece of property owned by a particular person (CU175)
Why not include taxes as takings?
What problem would the government have then?
(ii) "taken"
Why not just make the government buy it?
Government typically does make offers first
"In general, the
government should only take private property with compensation to provide a public good
when transaction costs preclude purchasing the necessary property." (CU177)
Advantage: avoids holdout problem
the seller's version of the free rider
"a good economic argument for eminent domain. . . is that it is
necessary to prevent monopoly." (P55)
Disadvantage: risk of under-valuing property to its owner