III. Property
D. Conflicting property rights
1. Incompatible uses (cont'd.)
b. In practice
Continue worksheet
Fontainebleau Hotel Corp. v. Forty-Five Twenty-Five, Inc. 114 So.2d 357 (1959) -- Eden Roc will be harmed by Fontainbleau (name misspelled in citation title in Lexis-Nexis)
Illustrates easement remedy w/o
liability for damages
Transaction costs may be high even in small-number cases.
Estancias Dallas Corp. v. Schultz, 500 S.W. 2d 217 (1973)
Illustrates the
injunction remedy without liability for damages.
Considers joint value.
Boomer v.
Atlantic Cement Co. 26 N.Y.2d 219 (1970)
What are the facts of the
case?
Illustrates easement with liability for damages
Raises the contrast between temporary and permanent damages
Expresses a preference for legislative policy for handling pollution
Spur Industries v. Del E. Webb Development (1972)
Illustrates injunction with liability for damages
Illustrates the reciprocal nature of incentives to internalize externalities
Legal costs include costs of (1) getting information and (2) court errors
There is no perfect/universal set of rules--all rules face tradeoffs
(1) Low transaction costs favor property right remedies--injunction/easement
For private parties: Property
and liability rights both --> efficient outcome
For the courts: property rights are cheaper to administer
Ex: difficult to determine damages when Windsong satellite
strays into Orbitcom's satellite orbit. (CU105)
"Bright line" rules:
predictable and cheap
"General rules that yield easily predictable results are
sometimes referred to bright line rules (to reduce uncertainty and rent seeking);
rules that require a case-by-case decision by the courts are referred to as standards. (F41)
(2) High
transaction costs relative to legal costs favor damage remedies
"Private bargaining is
unlikely to succeed in disputes involving a large number of geographically dispersed
people because communication costs are high, monitoring is costly, and strategic behavior
is likely to occur. . . . In these cases, damages are the preferred remedy." (CU106)
Calabresi, Guido, and A. Douglas Melamed. "Property rules,
liability rules, and inalienability: One view of the cathedral." Harvard Law Review
85 (1972): 1089. (CU105)
When there are free-rider problems (holdout or false valuations),
"an argument can readily be made for moving from a property rule to a liability rule.
If society can remove from the market the valuation of each tract of land, decide the
value collectively, and impose it, then the holdout problem is gone. Similarly, if society
can value collectively each individual citizen's desire to have a park and charge him a
'benefits' tax based upon it, the freeloader problem is gone." (LEA195)
High transaction costs are
commonplace
Especially with large stakes: Ex: Boomer v.
Atlantic Cement:
cost to plaintiff = 185K; injunction cost to cement firm= 45M =>
much room to negotiate and bluff.
"This expensive bargaining was avoided by the court's novel
remedial approach, although a simple alternative would have been, by a balancing of the
costs to the respective parties, to have found that the plant was not a nuisance."
(P71)
And even in small-number cases
Fountainebleau Hotel Corp. v. Forty-Five Twenty-Five, Inc. 114
So.2d 357 (1959) <-- "spite"
and bilateral monopoly
(2.1) Permanent or temporary damages?
Permanent in Boomer v. Atlantic Cement Co. 26 N.Y.2d 219 (1970)
Advantage to permanent damages:
eliminates future litigation costs
Advantage to temporary damages: preserves incentive to innovate (Ex: pointed out in the dissent in Boomer v. Atlantic Cement Co.
"[T]emporary damages tend to be more
efficient given easily measured damages and rapid innovation. Conversely, permanent
damages tend to be more efficient given costly measurement of damages and slow
innovation." (CU170)
Example: easements for overflights
easements for overflights are hard because of incentives
from alternative options (holdouts with easement purchases; no incentive to abate after
eminent domain, etc.) (P63)