KEWANEE OIL CO. v. BICRON CORP. ET AL.
No. 73-187
SUPREME COURT OF THE UNITED STATES
416 U.S. 470; 94 S. Ct. 1879; 40 L. Ed. 2d 315; 1974 U.S. LEXIS 134; 181 U.S.P.Q. (BNA)
673; 69 Ohio Op. 2d 235
January 9, 1974, Argued
May 13, 1974, Decided
PRIOR HISTORY:
CERTIORARI TO THE UNITED STATES COURT OF APPEALS FOR THE SIXTH CIRCUIT.
DISPOSITION: 478 F.2d 1074, reversed and remanded for reinstatement of District
Court Judgment.
SUMMARY: An unincorporated division of plaintiff is a leading manufacturer of a
type of synthetic crystal useful in the detection of ionizing radiation. This manufacturer
developed, by 1966, a novel 17-inch crystal as a result of many processes and
manufacturing techniques, some of which the manufacturer considered to be trade secrets.
The individual defendants are former employees of the manufacturer who formed or later
joined the corporate defendant. As a condition of their former employment with the
manufacturer, they executed at least one agreement each requiring the signer not to
disclose confidential information or trade secrets obtained as employees of the
manufacturer. The corporate defendant, formed in August 1969, was to compete with the
manufacturer in the production of the crystals and by April 1970 had grown a 17-inch
crystal. The plaintiff thereupon instituted a diversity action in the United States
District Court for the Northern District of Ohio seeking injunctive relief and damages for
the misappropriation of trade secrets. The District Court, applying Ohio trade secrets
law, granted a permanent injunction against the disclosure or use by the defendants of 20
of the 40 claimed trade secrets. Although holding that the District Court's findings of
fact were not clearly erroneous, the Court of Appeals for the Sixth Circuit reversed the
District Court on the ground that Ohio's trade secret laws were in conflict with the
patent laws of the United States (478 F2d 1074).
On certiorari, the United States Supreme Court reversed and remanded the case to the Court
of Appeals with directions to reinstate the judgment of the District Court. In an opinion
by Burger, Ch. J., expressing the view of five members of the Court, it was held that
state trade secret protection was not pre-empted by operation of the federal patent laws.
Marshall, J., concurred in the result, expressing the view that Congress, in enacting the
patent laws, intended merely to offer inventors a limited monopoly in exchange for
disclosure of their invention.
Douglas, J., joined by Brennan, J., dissented on the ground that the injunction granted by
the District Court was pre-empted by the federal patent laws.
Powell, J., did not participate.
JUDGES: Burger, C. J., delivered the opinion of the Court, in which Stewart, White,
Blackmun, and Rehnquist, JJ., joined. Marshall, J., filed an opinion concurring in the
result, post, p. 493. Douglas, J., filed a dissenting opinion, in which Brennan, J.,
joined, post, p. 495. Powell, J., took no part in the decision of the case.
OPINION: MR. CHIEF JUSTICE BURGER delivered the opinion of the Court.
We granted certiorari to resolve a question on which there is a conflict in the courts of
appeals: whether state trade secret protection is pre-empted by operation of the federal
patent law. In the instant case the Court of Appeals for the Sixth Circuit held that there
was preemption. The Courts of Appeals for the Second, Fourth, Fifth, and Ninth Circuits
have reached the opposite conclusion.
Harshaw Chemical Co., an unincorporated division of petitioner, is a leading manufacturer
of a type of synthetic crystal which is useful in the detection of ionizing radiation. In
1949 Harshaw commenced research into the growth of this type crystal and was able to
produce one less than two inches in diameter. By 1966, as the result of expenditures in
excess of $ 1 million, Harshaw was able to grow a 17-inch crystal, something no one else
had done previously. Harshaw had developed many processes, procedures, and manufacturing
techniques in the purification of raw materials and the growth and encapsulation of the
crystals which enabled it to accomplish this feat. Some of these processes Harshaw
considers to be trade secrets.
The individual respondents are former employees of Harshaw who formed or later joined
respondent Bicron. While at Harshaw the individual respondents executed, as a condition of
employment, at least one agreement each, requiring them not to disclose confidential
information or trade secrets obtained as employees of Harshaw. Bicron was formed in August
1969 to compete with Harshaw in the production of the crystals, and by April 1970, had
grown a 17-inch crystal.
Petitioner brought this diversity action in United States District Court for the Northern
District of Ohio seeking injunctive relief and damages for the misappropriation of trade
secrets. The District Court, applying Ohio trade secret law, granted a permanent
injunction against the disclosure or use by respondents of 20 of the 40 claimed trade
secrets until such time as the trade secrets had been released to the public, had
otherwise generally become available to the public, or had been obtained by respondents
from sources having the legal right to convey the information.
The Court of Appeals for the Sixth Circuit held that the findings of fact by the District
Court were not clearly erroneous, and that it was evident from the record that the
individual respondents appropriated to the benefit of Bicron secret information on
processes obtained while they were employees at Harshaw. Further, the Court of Appeals
held that the District Court properly applied Ohio law relating to trade secrets.
Nevertheless, the Court of Appeals reversed the District Court, finding Ohio's trade
secret law to be in conflict with the patent laws of the United States. The Court of
Appeals reasoned that Ohio could not grant monopoly protection to processes and
manufacturing techniques that were appropriate subjects for consideration under 35 U. S.
C. § 101 for a federal patent but which had been in commercial use for over one year and
so were no longer eligible for patent protection under 35 U. S. C. § 102 (b).
We hold that Ohio's law of trade secrets is not preempted by the patent laws of the United
States, and, accordingly, we reverse.
II
Ohio has adopted the widely relied-upon definition of a trade secret found at Restatement
of Torts § 757, comment b (1939). B. F. Goodrich Co. v. Wohlgemuth,
117 Ohio App. 493, 498, 192 N. E. 2d 99, 104 (1963); W. R. Grace & Co. v. Hargadine,
392 F.2d 9, 14 (CA6 1968). According to the Restatement,
"[a] trade secret may consist of any formula, pattern, device or compilation of
information which is used in one's business, and which gives him an opportunity to obtain
an advantage over competitors who do not know or use it. It may be a formula for a
chemical compound, a process of manufacturing, treating or preserving materials, a pattern
for a machine or other device, or a list of customers."
The subject of a trade secret must be secret, and must not be of public knowledge or of a
general knowledge in the trade or business. B. F. Goodrich Co. v. Wohlgemuth,
supra, at 499, 192 N. E. 2d, at 104; National Tube Co. v. Eastern Tube Co.,
3 Ohio C. C. R. (n. s.) 459, 462 (1902), aff'd, 69 Ohio St. 560, 70 N. E. 1127 (1903).
This necessary element of secrecy is not lost, however, if the holder of the trade secret
reveals the trade secret to another "in confidence, and under an implied obligation
not to use or disclose it." Cincinnati Bell Foundry Co. v. Dodds, 10
Ohio Dec. Reprint 154, 156, 19 Weekly L. Bull. 84 (Super. Ct. 1887). These others may
include those of the holder's "employees to whom it is necessary to confide it, in
order to apply it to the uses for which it is intended." National Tube Co. v. Eastern
Tube Co., supra, at 462. Often the recipient of confidential knowledge of the subject
of a trade secret is a licensee of its holder. See Lear, Inc. v. Adkins, 395
U.S. 653 (1969).
The protection accorded the trade secret holder is against the disclosure or unauthorized
use of the trade secret by those to whom the secret has been confided under the express or
implied restriction of nondisclosure or nonuse. The law also protects the holder of a
trade secret against disclosure or use when the knowledge is gained, not by the owner's
volition, but by some "improper means," Restatement of Torts § 757 (a), which
may include theft, wiretapping, or even aerial reconnaissance. A trade secret law,
however, does not offer protection against discovery by fair and honest means, such as by
independent invention, accidental disclosure, or by so-called reverse engineering, that is
by starting with the known product and working backward to divine the process which aided
in its development or manufacture.
Novelty, in the patent law sense, is not required for a trade secret, W. R. Grace &
Co. v. Hargadine, 392 F.2d, at 14. "Quite clearly discovery is something
less than invention." A. O. Smith Corp. v. Petroleum Iron Works Co., 73
F.2d 531, 538 (CA6 1934), modified to increase scope of injunction, 74 F.2d 934 (1935).
However, some novelty will be required if merely because that which does not possess
novelty is usually known; secrecy, in the context of trade secrets, thus implies at least
minimal novelty.
The subject matter of a patent is limited to a "process, machine, manufacture, or
composition of matter, or . . . improvement thereof," 35 U. S. C. § 101, which
fulfills the three conditions of novelty and utility as articulated and defined in 35 U.
S. C. §§ 101 and 102, and nonobviousness, as set out in 35 U. S. C. § 103. If an
invention meets the rigorous statutory tests for the issuance of a patent, the patent is
granted, for a period of 17 years, giving what has been described as the "right of
exclusion," R. Ellis, Patent Assignments and Licenses § 4, p. 7 (2d ed. 1943). This
protection goes not only to copying the subject matter, which is forbidden under the
Copyright Act, 17 U. S. C. § 1 et seq., but also to independent creation.
III
The first issue we deal with is whether the States are forbidden to act at all in the area
of protection of the kinds of intellectual property which may make up the subject matter
of trade secrets.
Article I, § 8, cl. 8, of the Constitution grants to the Congress the power
"to promote the Progress of Science and useful Arts, by securing for limited Times to
Authors and Inventors the exclusive Right to their respective Writings and Discoveries . .
. ."
In the 1972 Term, in Goldstein v. California, 412 U.S. 546 (1973), we held
that the cl. 8 grant of power to Congress was not exclusive and that, at least in the case
of writings, the States were not prohibited from encouraging and protecting the efforts of
those within their borders by appropriate legislation. The States could, therefore,
protect against the unauthorized rerecording for sale of performances fixed on records or
tapes, even though those performances qualified as "writings" in the
constitutional sense and Congress was empowered to legislate regarding such performances
and could pre-empt the area if it chose to do so. This determination was premised on the
great diversity of interests in our Nation -- the essentially nonuniform character of the
appreciation of intellectual achievements in the various States. Evidence for this came
from patents granted by the States in the 18th century. 412 U.S., at 557.
Just as the States may exercise regulatory power over writings so may the States regulate
with respect to discoveries. States may hold diverse viewpoints in protecting intellectual
property relating to invention as they do in protecting the intellectual property relating
to the subject matter of copyright. The only limitation on the States is that in
regulating the area of patents and copyrights they do not conflict with the operation of
the laws in this area passed by Congress, and it is to that more difficult question we now
turn.
IV
The question of whether the trade secret law of Ohio is void under the Supremacy Clause
involves a consideration of whether that law "stands as an obstacle to the
accomplishment and execution of the full purposes and objectives of Congress." Hines
v. Davidowitz, 312 U.S. 52, 67 (1941). See Florida Avocado Growers v. Paul,
373 U.S. 132, 141 (1963). We stated in Sears, Roebuck & Co. v. Stiffel Co.,
376 U.S. 225, 229 (1964), that when state law touches upon the area of federal statutes
enacted pursuant to constitutional authority, "it is 'familiar doctrine' that the
federal policy 'may not be set at naught, or its benefits denied' by the state law. Sola
Elec. Co. v. Jefferson Elec. Co., 317 U.S. 173, 176 (1942). This is true, of
course, even if the state law is enacted in the exercise of otherwise undoubted state
power."
The laws which the Court of Appeals in this case held to be in conflict with the Ohio law
of trade secrets were the patent laws passed by the Congress in the unchallenged exercise
of its clear power under Art. I, § 8, cl. 8, of the Constitution. The patent law does not
explicitly endorse or forbid the operation of trade secret law. However, as we have noted,
if the scheme of protection developed by Ohio respecting trade secrets "clashes with
the objectives of the federal patent laws," Sears, Roebuck & Co. v. Stiffel
Co., supra, at 231, then the state law must fall. To determine whether the Ohio law
"clashes" with the federal law it is helpful to examine the objectives of both
the patent and trade secret laws.
The stated objective of the Constitution in granting the power to Congress to legislate in
the area of intellectual property is to "promote the Progress of Science and useful
Arts." The patent laws promote this progress by offering a right of exclusion for a
limited period as an incentive to inventors to risk the often enormous costs in terms of
time, research, and development. The productive effort thereby fostered will have a
positive effect on society through the introduction of new products and processes of
manufacture into the economy, and the emanations by way of increased employment and better
lives for our citizens. In return for the right of exclusion -- this "reward for
inventions," Universal Oil Co. v. Globe Co., 322 U.S. 471, 484 (1944)
-- the patent laws impose upon the inventor a requirement of disclosure. To insure
adequate and full disclosure so that upon the expiration of the 17-year period "the
knowledge of the invention enures to the people, who are thus enabled without restriction
to practice it and profit by its use," United States v. Dubilier Condenser
Corp., 289 U.S. 178, 187 (1933), the patent laws require that the patent application
shall include a full and clear description of the invention and "of the manner and
process of making and using it" so that any person skilled in the art may make and
use the invention. 35 U. S. C. § 112. When a patent is granted and the information
contained in it is circulated to the general public and those especially skilled in the
trade, such additions to the general store of knowledge are of such importance to the
public weal that the Federal Government is willing to pay the high price of 17 years of
exclusive use for its disclosure, which disclosure, it is assumed, will stimulate ideas
and the eventual development of further significant advances in the art. The Court has
also articulated another policy of the patent law: that which is in the public domain
cannot be removed therefrom by action of the States.
"Federal law requires that all ideas in general circulation be dedicated to the
common good unless they are protected by a valid patent." Lear, Inc. v. Adkins,
395 U.S., at 668....
The maintenance of standards of commercial ethics and the encouragement of invention are
the broadly stated policies behind trade secret law. "The necessity of good faith and
honest, fair dealing, is the very life and spirit of the commercial world." National
Tube Co. v. Eastern Tube Co., 3 Ohio C. C. R. (n. s.), at 462. In A. O.
Smith Corp. v. Petroleum Iron Works Co., 73 F.2d, at 539, the Court emphasized
that even though a discovery may not be patentable, that does not
"destroy the value of the discovery to one who makes it, or advantage the competitor
who by unfair means, or as the beneficiary of a broken faith, obtains the desired
knowledge without himself paying the price in labor, money, or machines expended by the
discoverer."
In Wexler v. Greenberg, 399 Pa. 569, 578-579, 160 A. 2d 430, 434-435 (1960),
the Pennsylvania Supreme Court noted the importance of trade secret protection to the
subsidization of research and development and to increased economic efficiency within
large companies through the dispersion of responsibilities for creative developments.
Having now in mind the objectives of both the patent and trade secret law, we turn to an
examination of the interaction of these systems of protection of intellectual property --
one established by the Congress and the other by a State -- to determine whether and under
what circumstances the latter might constitute "too great an encroachment on the
federal patent system to be tolerated." Sears, Roebuck & Co. v. Stiffel
Co., 376 U.S., at 232.
As we noted earlier, trade secret law protects items which would not be proper subjects
for consideration for patent protection under 35 U. S. C. § 101. As in the case of the
recordings in Goldstein v. California, Congress, with respect to
nonpatentable subject matter, "has drawn no balance; rather, it has left the area
unattended, and no reason exists why the State should not be free to act." Goldstein
v. California, supra, at 570 (footnote omitted).
Since no patent is available for a discovery, however useful, novel, and nonobvious,
unless it falls within one of the express categories of patentable subject matter of 35 U.
S. C. § 101, the holder of such a discovery would have no reason to apply for a patent
whether trade secret protection existed or not. Abolition of trade secret protection
would, therefore, not result in increased disclosure to the public of discoveries in the
area of nonpatentable subject matter. Also, it is hard to see how the public would be
benefited by disclosure of customer lists or advertising campaigns; in fact, keeping such
items secret encourages businesses to initiate new and individualized plans of operation,
and constructive competition results. This, in turn, leads to a greater variety of
business methods than would otherwise be the case if privately developed marketing and
other data were passed illicitly among firms involved in the same enterprise.
Congress has spoken in the area of those discoveries which fall within one of the
categories of patentable subject matter of 35 U. S. C. § 101 and which are, therefore, of
a nature that would be subject to consideration for a patent. Processes, machines,
manufactures, compositions of matter, and improvements thereof, which meet the tests of
utility, novelty, and nonobviousness are entitled to be patented, but those which do not,
are not. The question remains whether those items which are proper subjects for
consideration for a patent may also have available the alternative protection accorded by
trade secret law.
Certainly the patent policy of encouraging invention is not disturbed by the existence of
another form of incentive to invention. In this respect the two systems are not and never
would be in conflict. Similarly, the policy that matter once in the public domain must
remain in the public domain is not incompatible with the existence of trade secret
protection. By definition a trade secret has not been placed in the public domain.
The more difficult objective of the patent law to reconcile with trade secret law is that
of disclosure, the quid pro quo of the right to exclude. Universal Oil Co.
v. Globe Co., 322 U.S., at 484. We are helped in this stage of the analysis by
Judge Henry Friendly's opinion in Painton & Co. v. Bourns, Inc., 442
F.2d 216 (CA2 1971). There the Court of Appeals thought it useful, in determining whether
inventors will refrain because of the existence of trade secret law from applying for
patents, thereby depriving the public from learning of the invention, to distinguish
between three categories of trade secrets:
"(1) the trade secret believed by its owner to constitute a validly patentable
invention; (2) the trade secret known to its owner not to be so patentable; and (3) the
trade secret whose valid patentability is considered dubious." Id., at 224.
Trade secret protection in each of these categories would run against breaches of
confidence -- the employee and licensee situations -- and theft and other forms of
industrial espionage.
As to the trade secret known not to meet the standards of patentability, very little in
the way of disclosure would be accomplished by abolishing trade secret protection. With
trade secrets of nonpatentable subject matter, the patent alternative would not reasonably
be available to the inventor. "There can be no public interest in stimulating
developers of such [unpatentable] knowhow to flood an overburdened Patent Office with
applications [for] what they do not consider patentable." Ibid. The mere
filing of applications doomed to be turned down by the Patent Office will bring forth no
new public knowledge or enlightenment, since under federal statute and regulation patent
applications and abandoned patent applications are held by the Patent Office in confidence
and are not open to public inspection. 35 U. S. C. § 122; 37 CFR § 1.14 (b).
Even as the extension of trade secret protection to patentable subject matter that the
owner knows will not meet the standards of patentability will not conflict with the patent
policy of disclosure, it will have a decidedly beneficial effect on society. Trade secret
law will encourage invention in areas where patent law does not reach, and will prompt the
independent innovator to proceed with the discovery and exploitation of his invention.
Competition is fostered and the public is not deprived of the use of valuable, if not
quite patentable, invention.
Even if trade secret protection against the faithless employee were abolished, inventive
and exploitive effort in the area of patentable subject matter that did not meet the
standards of patentability would continue, although at a reduced level. Alternatively with
the effort that remained, however, would come an increase in the amount of self-help that
innovative companies would employ. Knowledge would be widely dispersed among the employees
of those still active in research. Security precautions necessarily would be increased,
and salaries and fringe benefits of those few officers or employees who had to know the
whole of the secret invention would be fixed in an amount thought sufficient to assure
their loyalty. Smaller companies would be placed at a distinct economic disadvantage,
since the costs of this kind of self-help could be great, and the cost to the public of
the use of this invention would be increased. The innovative entrepreneur with limited
resources would tend to confine his research efforts to himself and those few he felt he
could trust without the ultimate assurance of legal protection against breaches of
confidence. As a result, organized scientific and technological research could become
fragmented, and society, as a whole, would suffer.
Another problem that would arise if state trade secret protection were precluded is in the
area of licensing others to exploit secret processes. The holder of a trade secret would
not likely share his secret with a manufacturer who cannot be placed under binding legal
obligation to pay a license fee or to protect the secret. The result would be to hoard
rather than disseminate knowledge. Painton & Co. v. Bourns, Inc., 442
F.2d, at 223. Instead, then, of licensing others to use his invention and making the most
efficient use of existing manufacturing and marketing structures within the industry, the
trade secret holder would tend either to limit his utilization of the invention, thereby
depriving the public of the maximum benefit of its use, or engage in the time-consuming
and economically wasteful enterprise of constructing duplicative manufacturing and
marketing mechanisms for the exploitation of the invention. The detrimental misallocation
of resources and economic waste that would thus take place if trade secret protection were
abolished with respect to employees or licensees cannot be justified by reference to any
policy that the federal patent law seeks to advance.
Nothing in the patent law requires that States refrain from action to prevent industrial
espionage. In addition to the increased costs for protection from burglary, wiretapping,
bribery, and the other means used to misappropriate trade secrets, there is the inevitable
cost to the basic decency of society when one firm steals from another. A most fundamental
human right, that of privacy, is threatened when industrial espionage is condoned or is
made profitable; the state interest in denying profit to such illegal ventures is
unchallengeable.
The next category of patentable subject matter to deal with is the invention whose holder
has a legitimate doubt as to its patentability. The risk of eventual patent invalidity by
the courts and the costs associated with that risk may well impel some with a good-faith
doubt as to patentability not to take the trouble to seek to obtain and defend patent
protection for their discoveries, regardless of the existence of trade secret protection.
Trade secret protection would assist those inventors in the more efficient exploitation of
their discoveries and not conflict with the patent law. In most cases of genuine doubt as
to patent validity the potential rewards of patent protection are so far superior to those
accruing to holders of trade secrets, that the holders of such inventions will seek patent
protection, ignoring the trade secret route. For those inventors "on the line"
as to whether to seek patent protection, the abolition of trade secret protection might
encourage some to apply for a patent who otherwise would not have done so. For some of
those so encouraged, no patent will be granted and the result
"will have been an unnecessary postponement in the divulging of the trade secret to
persons willing to pay for it. If [the patent does issue], it may well be invalid, yet
many will prefer to pay a modest royalty than to contest it, even though Lear
allows them to accept a license and pursue the contest without paying royalties while the
fight goes on. The result in such a case would be unjustified royalty payments from many
who would prefer not to pay them rather than agreed fees from one or a few who are
entirely willing to do so." Painton & Co. v. Bourns, Inc., 442
F.2d, at 225.
The point is that those who might be encouraged to file for patents by the absence of
trade secret law will include inventors possessing the chaff as well as the wheat. Some of
the chaff -- the nonpatentable discoveries -- will be thrown out by the Patent Office, but
in the meantime society will have been deprived of use of those discoveries through trade
secret-protected licensing. Some of the chaff may not be thrown out. This Court has noted
the difference between the standards used by the Patent Office and the courts to determine
patentability. Graham v. John Deere Co., 383 U.S. 1, 18 (1966). In Lear,
Inc. v. Adkins, 395 U.S. 653 (1969), the Court thought that an invalid patent
was so serious a threat to the free use of ideas already in the public domain that the
Court permitted licensees of the patent holder to challenge the validity of the patent.
Better had the invalid patent never been issued. More of those patents would likely issue
if trade secret law were abolished. Eliminating trade secret law for the doubtfully
patentable invention is thus likely to have deleterious effects on society and patent
policy which we cannot say are balanced out by the speculative gain which might result
from the encouragement of some inventors with doubtfully patentable inventions which
deserve patent protection to come forward and apply for patents. There is no conflict,
then, between trade secret law and the patent law policy of disclosure, at least insofar
as the first two categories of patentable subject matter are concerned.
The final category of patentable subject matter to deal with is the clearly patentable
invention, i. e., that invention which the owner believes to meet the standards of
patentability. It is here that the federal interest in disclosure is at its peak; these
inventions, novel, useful and nonobvious, are "'the things which are worth to the
public the embarrassment of an exclusive patent.'" Graham v. John Deere
Co., supra, at 9 (quoting Thomas Jefferson). The interest of the public is that the
bargain of 17 years of exclusive use in return for disclosure be accepted. If a State,
through a system of protection, were to cause a substantial risk that holders of
patentable inventions would not seek patents, but rather would rely on the state
protection, we would be compelled to hold that such a system could not constitutionally
continue to exist. In the case of trade secret law no reasonable risk of deterrence from
patent application by those who can reasonably expect to be granted patents exists.
Trade secret law provides far weaker protection in many respects than the patent law.
While trade secret law does not forbid the discovery of the trade secret by fair and
honest means, e. g., independent creation or reverse engineering, patent law
operates "against the world," forbidding any use of the invention for whatever
purpose for a significant length of time. The holder of a trade secret also takes a
substantial risk that the secret will be passed on to his competitors, by theft or by
breach of a confidential relationship, in a manner not easily susceptible of discovery or
proof. Painton & Co. v. Bourns, Inc., 442 F.2d, at 224. Where patent law
acts as a barrier, trade secret law functions relatively as a sieve. The possibility that
an inventor who believes his invention meets the standards of patentability will sit back,
rely on trade secret law, and after one year of use forfeit any right to patent
protection, 35 U. S. C. § 102 (b), is remote indeed.
Nor does society face much risk that scientific or technological progress will be impeded
by the rare inventor with a patentable invention who chooses trade secret protection over
patent protection. The ripeness-of-time concept of invention, developed from the study of
the many independent multiple discoveries in history, predicts that if a particular
individual had not made a particular discovery others would have, and in probably a
relatively short period of time. If something is to be discovered at all very likely it
will be discovered by more than one person. Singletons and Multiples in Science (1961), in
R. Merton, The Sociology of Science 343 (1973); J. Cole & S. Cole, Social
Stratification in Science 12-13, 229-230 (1973); Ogburn & Thomas, Are Inventions
Inevitable?, 37 Pol. Sci. Q. 83 (1922). Even were an inventor to keep his discovery
completely to himself, something that neither the patent nor trade secret laws forbid,
there is a high probability that it will be soon independently developed. If the
invention, though still a trade secret, is put into public use, the competition is alerted
to the existence of the inventor's solution to the problem and may be encouraged to make
an extra effort to independently find the solution thus known to be possible. The inventor
faces pressures not only from private industry, but from the skilled scientists who work
in our universities and our other great publicly supported centers of learning and
research.
We conclude that the extension of trade secret protection to clearly patentable inventions
does not conflict with the patent policy of disclosure. Perhaps because trade secret law
does not produce any positive effects in the area of clearly patentable inventions, as
opposed to the beneficial effects resulting from trade secret protection in the areas of
the doubtfully patentable and the clearly unpatentable inventions, it has been suggested
that partial pre-emption may be appropriate, and that courts should refuse to apply trade
secret protection to inventions which the holder should have patented, and which would
have been, thereby, disclosed. However, since there is no real possibility that trade
secret law will conflict with the federal policy favoring disclosure of clearly patentable
inventions partial pre-emption is inappropriate. Partial pre-emption, furthermore, could
well create serious problems for state courts in the administration of trade secret law.
As a preliminary matter in trade secret actions, state courts would be obliged to
distinguish between what a reasonable inventor would and would not correctly consider to
be clearly patentable, with the holder of the trade secret arguing that the invention was
not patentable and the misappropriator of the trade secret arguing its undoubted novelty,
utility, and nonobviousness. Federal courts have a difficult enough time trying to
determine whether an invention, narrowed by the patent application procedure and fixed in
the specifications which describe the invention for which the patent has been granted, is
patentable. Although state courts in some circumstances must join federal courts in
judging whether an issued patent is valid, Lear, Inc. v. Adkins, supra, it
would be undesirable to impose the almost impossible burden on state courts to determine
the patentability -- in fact and in the mind of a reasonable inventor -- of a discovery
which has not been patented and remains entirely uncircumscribed by expert analysis in the
administrative process. Neither complete nor partial pre-emption of state trade secret law
is justified.
Our conclusion that patent law does not pre-empt trade secret law is in accord with prior
cases of this Court. Universal Oil Co. v. Globe Co., 322 U.S., at 484; United
States v. Dubilier Condenser Corp., 289 U.S., at 186-187; Becher v. Contoure
Laboratories, 279 U.S. 388, 391 (1929); Du Pont Powder Co. v. Masland,
244 U.S. 100, 102 (1917); Dr. Miles Medical Co. v. Park & Sons Co., 220
U.S. 373, 402-403 (1911); Board of Trade v. Christie Grain & Stock Co.,
198 U.S. 236, 250-251 (1905).Trade secret law and patent law have co-existed in this
country for over one hundred years. Each has its particular role to play, and the
operation of one does not take away from the need for the other. Trade secret law
encourages the development and exploitation of those items of lesser or different
invention than might be accorded protection under the patent laws, but which items still
have an important part to play in the technological and scientific advancement of the
Nation. Trade secret law promotes the sharing of knowledge, and the efficient operation of
industry; it permits the individual inventor to reap the rewards of his labor by
contracting with a company large enough to develop and exploit it. Congress, by its
silence over these many years, has seen the wisdom of allowing the States to enforce trade
secret protection. Until Congress takes affirmative action to the contrary, States should
be free to grant protection to trade secrets.
Since we hold that Ohio trade secret law is not preempted by the federal patent law, the
judgment of the Court of Appeals for the Sixth Circuit is reversed, and the case is
remanded to the Court of Appeals with directions to reinstate the judgment of the District
Court.
It is so ordered.
MR. JUSTICE POWELL took no part in the decision of this case.
CONCUR: MR. JUSTICE MARSHALL, concurring in the result.
Unlike the Court, I do not believe that the possibility that an inventor with a patentable
invention will rely on state trade secret law rather than apply for a patent is
"remote indeed." Ante, at 490. State trade secret law provides
substantial protection to the inventor who intends to use or sell the invention himself
rather than license it to others, protection which in its unlimited duration is clearly
superior to the 17-year monopoly afforded by the patent laws. I have no doubt that the
existence of trade secret protection provides in some instances a substantial disincentive
to entrance into the patent system, and thus deprives society of the benefits of public
disclosure of the invention which it is the policy of the patent laws to encourage. This
case may well be such an instance.
But my view of sound policy in this area does not dispose of this case. Rather, the
question presented in this case is whether Congress, in enacting the patent laws, intended
merely to offer inventors a limited monopoly in exchange for disclosure of their
invention, or instead to exert pressure on inventors to enter into this exchange by
withdrawing any alternative possibility of legal protection for their inventions. I am
persuaded that the former is the case. State trade secret laws and the federal patent laws
have co-existed for many, many years. During this time, Congress has repeatedly
demonstrated its full awareness of the existence of the trade secret system, without any
indication of disapproval. Indeed, Congress has in a number of instances given explicit
federal protection to trade secret information provided to federal agencies. See, e. g.,
5 U. S. C. § 552 (b)(4); 18 U. S. C. § 1905; see generally Appendix to Brief for
Petitioner. Because of this, I conclude that there is "neither such actual conflict
between the two schemes of regulation that both cannot stand in the same area, nor
evidence of a congressional design to preempt the field." Florida Avocado Growers
v. Paul, 373 U.S. 132, 141 (1963). I therefore concur in the result reached by the
majority of the Court.
DISSENT: MR. JUSTICE DOUGLAS, with whom MR. JUSTICE BRENNAN concurs, dissenting.
Today's decision is at war with the philosophy of Sears, Roebuck & Co. v. Stiffel
Co., 376 U.S. 225, and Compco Corp. v. Day-Brite Lighting, Inc., 376
U.S. 234. Those cases involved patents -- one of a pole lamp and one of fluorescent
lighting fixtures each of which was declared invalid. The lower courts held, however, that
though the patents were invalid the sale of identical or confusingly similar products to
the products of the patentees violated state unfair competition laws. We held that when an
article is unprotected by a patent, state law may not forbid others to copy it, because
every article not covered by a valid patent is in the public domain. Congress in the
patent laws decided that where no patent existed, free competition should prevail; that
where a patent is rightfully issued, the right to exclude others should obtain for no
longer than 17 years, and that the States may not "under some other law, such as that
forbidding unfair competition, give protection of a kind that clashes with the objectives
of the federal patent laws," 376 U.S., at 231.
The product involved in this suit, sodium iodide synthetic crystals, was a product that
could be patented but was not. Harshaw the inventor apparently contributed greatly to the
technology in that field by developing processes, procedures, and techniques that produced
much larger crystals than any competitor. These processes, procedures, and techniques were
also patentable; but no patent was sought. Rather Harshaw sought to protect its trade
secrets by contracts with its employees. And the District Court found that, as a result of
those secrecy precautions, "not sufficient disclosure occurred so as to place the
claimed trade secrets in the public domain"; and those findings were sustained by the
Court of Appeals.
The District Court issued a permanent injunction against respondents, ex-employees,
restraining them from using the processes used by Harshaw. By a patent which would require
full disclosure Harshaw could have obtained a 17-year monopoly against the world. By the
District Court's injunction, which the Court approves and reinstates, Harshaw gets a
permanent injunction running into perpetuity against respondents. In Sears, as in
the present case, an injunction against the unfair competitor issued. We said: "To
allow a State by use of its law of unfair competition to prevent the copying of an article
which represents too slight an advance to be patented would be to permit the State to
block off from the public something which federal law has said belongs to the public. The
result would be that while federal law grants only 14 or 17 years' protection to genuine
inventions, see 35 U. S. C. §§ 154, 173, States could allow perpetual protection to
articles too lacking in novelty to merit any patent at all under federal constitutional
standards. This would be too great an encroachment on the federal patent system to be
tolerated." 376 U.S., at 231-232.
The conflict with the patent laws is obvious. The decision of Congress to adopt a patent
system was based on the idea that there will be much more innovation if discoveries are
disclosed and patented than there will be when everyone works in secret. Society thus
fosters a free exchange of technological information at the cost of a limited 17-year
monopoly.
A trade secret, unlike a patent, has no property dimension. That was the view of the Court
of Appeals, 478 F.2d 1074, 1081; and its decision is supported by what Mr. Justice Holmes
said in Du Pont Powder Co. v. Masland, 244 U.S. 100, 102:
"The word property as applied to trade-marks and trade secrets is an unanalyzed
expression of certain secondary consequences of the primary fact that the law makes some
rudimentary requirements of good faith. Whether the plaintiffs have any valuable secret or
not the defendant knows the facts, whatever they are, through a special confidence that he
accepted. The property may be denied but the confidence cannot be. Therefore the starting
point for the present matter is not property or due process of law, but that the defendant
stood in confidential relations with the plaintiffs, or one of them. These have given
place to hostility, and the first thing to be made sure of is that the defendant shall not
fraudulently abuse the trust reposed in him. It is the usual incident of confidential
relations. If there is any disadvantage in the fact that he knew the plaintiffs' secrets
he must take the burden with the good."
A suit to redress theft of a trade secret is grounded in tort damages for breach of a
contract -- a historic remedy, Cataphote Corp. v. Hudson, 422 F.2d 1290.
Damages for breach of a confidential relation are not pre-empted by this patent law, but
an injunction against use is pre-empted because the patent law states the only monopoly
over trade secrets that is enforceable by specific performance; and that monopoly exacts
as a price full disclosure. A trade secret can be protected only by being kept secret.
Damages for breach of a contract are one thing; an injunction barring disclosure does
service for the protection accorded valid patents and is therefore pre-empted.
From the findings of fact of the lower courts, the process involved in this litigation was
unique, such a great discovery as to make its patentability a virtual certainty. Yet the
Court's opinion reflects a vigorous activist antipatent philosophy. My objection is not
because it is activist. This is a problem that involves no neutral principle. The
Constitution in Art. I, § 8, cl. 8, expresses the activist policy which Congress has
enforced by statutes. It is that constitutional policy which we should enforce, not our
individual notions of the public good.
I would affirm the judgment below.