Jim Whitney |
Case name: |
Otis F. Wood, Appellant, v. Lucy, Lady Duff-Gordon, Respondent |
Court: |
Court
of Appeals of New York |
Citation; Date: |
November
14, 1917, Argued December 4, 1917, Decided |
PROCEDURAL HISTORY |
|||
Trial court: |
Appeal court (if
relevant): |
||
Plaintiff: |
|
Appellant: |
Otis F. Wood |
Defendant: |
|
Respondent: |
Lucy,
Lady Duff-Gordon |
Facts of the case: |
|
Lucy Duff-Gordon is "a creator of
fashions." She is able to increase sales of fashionable products.
Manufacturers of dresses and like articles pay for Lucy’s certificate of
approval in order to increase sales. The things which she designs, fabrics,
parasols and what not, have a new value in the public mind when issued in her
name. She employed Otis Wood to help her to turn her product (basically
putting her name on things) into money. Otis Wood was to have the exclusive
right, subject always to Lucy’s approval, to place her endorsements on the
designs of others. Otis Wood was also to have the exclusive right to place
her own designs on sale, or to license others to market them. In return, Lucy
was to have one-half of "all profits and revenues" derived from any
contracts he might make. The exclusive right was to last at least one year
from April 1, 1915, and thereafter from year to year unless terminated by
notice of ninety days. Otis Wood says that he kept the contract on his part,
and that Lucy broke it. She placed her endorsement on fabrics, dresses and
millinery without Otis Wood’s knowledge, and withheld the profits. Otis Wood
sues Lucy for the damages, and the case comes here on demurrer. |
|
|
|
Remedy sought: |
Damages
resulting from Lucy putting her endorsement on products without the
plaintiff’s knowledge and for the withholding of profits. |
Court opinion (including key issues and
arguments): Both
parties signed the contract of employment. Lucy insists, however, that it
lacks the elements of a contract. She says that Otis Wood does not bind
himself to anything. It is true that he does not promise in so many words
that he will use reasonable efforts to place the defendant's endorsements and
market her designs. The court thinks, however, that such a promise is
fairly to be implied. A promise may
be lacking, and yet the whole writing may be "instinct with an
obligation," imperfectly expressed (Scott, J., in McCall Co. v.
Wright, 133 App. Div. 62; Moran v. Standard Oil Co., 211 N.
Y. 187, 198). If that is so, there is a contract. |
|
The
implication of a promise here finds support in many circumstances. First,
Lucy gave an exclusive privilege. She was to have no right for at
least a year to place her own endorsements or market her own designs except
through the agency of Otis Wood. The acceptance of the exclusive agency was
an assumption of its duties.... We are not to suppose that one party was to
be placed at the mercy of the other ( Hearn v. Stevens & Bro.,
111 App. Div. 101, 106; Russell v. Allerton, 108 N. Y. 288).
Secondly, "Otis F. Wood possesses a business organization adapted to the
placing of such endorsements as the said Lucy, Lady Duff-Gordon has
approved." The implication is that the plaintiff's business organization
will be used for the purpose for which it is adapted. But the terms of Lucy’s
compensation are even more significant. Her sole compensation for the grant
of an exclusive agency is to be one-half of all the profits resulting from
the plaintiff's efforts. Unless he gave his efforts, she could never get
anything. Without an implied promise, the transaction cannot have such
business "efficacy as both parties must have intended that at all events
it should have" (Bowen, L. J., in The Moorcock, 14 P. D. 64, 68).
But the contract does not stop there. The plaintiff goes on to promise that
he will account monthly for all moneys received by him, and that he will
take out all such patents and copyrights and trademarks as may in his
judgment be necessary to protect the rights and articles affected by the
agreement. It is true, of course, as the Appellate Division has said, that if
Otis Wood was under no duty to try to market designs or to place certificates
of endorsement, his promise to account for profits or take out copyrights would
be valueless. But in determining the intention of the parties, the promise has
a value. It helps to enforce the conclusion that the plaintiff had
some duties. His promise to pay the defendant one-half of the profits and
revenues resulting from the exclusive agency and to render accounts monthly,
was a promise to use reasonable efforts to bring profits and revenues into
existence.... |
|
|
|
Disposition of case: |
|
Rule
in favor of the Plaintiff |
ECONOMIC ANALYSIS OF THE CASE |
Wood
v. Duff-Gordon deals with the issue of implicit understandings. When negotiating a contract some gaps
within the agreement may be deliberate.
In order to cut down negotiation costs it is more efficient for some
fundamental aspects of a contract to be implied within the understanding
rather than explicitly stated in words.
The use of implicit understandings in contracts can lead to litigation
and increased costs. However, the
amount of money saved by not having to specifically word all facets of every
contract outweighs the court costs that may be incurred. The two parties could have explicitly
outlined every possible contractual obligation, however this would have been
a painstakingly long process. Instead,
it is more efficient to have a general outline of the terms and have both
parties accept the terms. It is more
economically efficient to assume that reasonable individuals will be able to
understand implicit obligations in a contract. As both Wood and Duff-Gordon are most likely reasonable
individuals, there was no reason for needlessly inflate negotiation
costs. Wood was correct in his
argument that Duff-Gordon did not uphold the exclusive rights set forth in
the contract. Therefore, the court made
the economically efficient decision in entitling Wood to damages resulting from
Duff-Gordon putting her endorsement on products without the plaintiff’s
knowledge and for the withholding of profits. The main issue raised in this case is the trade-off between
opportunism and the cost of litigation. |