Jim Whitney |
Case name: |
Peevyhouse
v. Garland Coal and Mining Co. |
Court: |
Supreme
Court of Oklahoma |
Citation; Date: |
1962 |
PROCEDURAL HISTORY |
|||
Trial court: |
Appeal court (if
relevant): |
||
Plaintiff: |
Peevyhouse |
Appellant: |
Peevyhouse |
Defendant: |
Garland
Coal and Mining Co. |
Respondent: |
Garland
Coal and Mining |
Facts of the case: |
|
Peevyhouse
family owned a farm that contained coal deposits. In November 1954, they leased their property to the Garland
Coal and Mining Co. for a five-year period.
During this five-year period, Garland Coal was to be ‘strip mining’
for coal from pits on the surface of the ground. The defendants had agreed in their contract with the Peevyhouse
to perform certain restorative and remedial work at the end of the lease
period. After the end of the
five-year contract, Garland refused to remove thousands of cubic yards of
dirt. The Peevyhouse family sued the Garland Coal company for $25,000 for
Breach of Contract, even though the actual cost of removing the dirt was
estimated at $29,000. |
|
|
|
Remedy sought: |
$25,000
for the non-removal of dirt left by Garland Coal after strip mining on
Peevyhouse property, which they had promised to remove, at the end of their
lease. |
|
|
Court opinion (including key issues and
arguments): |
|
One of the arguments presented by the court was
that the remedial work was not the main purpose of the contract and the
special clause about restorative work was only “incidental to the main object
involved.” Court also considered the
evidence presented that after the performance of the restoration the value of
the property would only increase by $300, which is far less than the cost of
performance of $29,000. Thus, the
court concluded that “where the economic benefit which would result to lessor
by full performance of the work is grossly disproportionate to the cost of
performance, the a damages which lessor may recover are limited to the
diminution in value resulting to the premises because of the
non-performance.” However, the
dissent argues that the contract was made in good faith and the Peevyhouse insisted
upon the remedial work or they would not have signed the contract. Both parties must have known what benefit
the contract will yield and Garland should not have been allowed to breach
the contract. |
|
|
|
Disposition of case: |
|
In the trial court, the court ruled in favor of
the plaintiffs for $5,000, much less than the ‘cost of performance,’ which
was estimated at $29,000. Although
they were not rewarded the full damages, they still receive much more than
the total value of their property, even after the remedial work is done. When the case was appealed and brought to
the Supreme Court the plaintiffs had their previous judgment modified and
reduced to $300. |
ECONOMIC ANALYSIS OF THE CASE |
The plaintiff entered into a contract, which as an
improvement could reduce his property value but he felt that the value that
would arise from the contract would be more beneficial. Thus, the plaintiff must have concluded
that the benefits would exceed the costs.
This case also illustrates an efficient breach because Garland Coal
Mining did not have to pay the cost of performance, which would have
benefited the plaintiff excessively.
The courts use the value rule instead of the cost of performance
because if the remedial work had been completed it would not have increased
the value of the property by an equal amount. This creates a positive incentive because parties will now
enter contracts under the assumption that they will at least be compensated
for any increase in value that they are entitled to if the contractor would
follow through with remedial work. However, as the dissent indicates, the plaintiff
entered the contract because they specifically requested the clause with
remedial work because they live on the farm and wish to retain the aesthetic
value of the property. The court
decision creates a negative incentive to enter into contracts because other
parties could breach the contract in a way, which does not benefit the
contractee. Another important consideration is that perhaps
the court should have considered specific performance. This means the court should have made
Garland perform the work and thus award Peevyhouse with the right to make
Garland perform the remedial work.
However, this does not necessarily mean that Garland has to do the
work, which would cost $29,000 and be inefficient. A more likely outcome would be that the two parties could now
bargain and find a more efficient solution where Peevyhouse would accept an
appropriate payment and Garland would not have to perform the work. This creates a positive incentive because parties
will now be more inclined to enter contracts because courts are likely to
award specific performance and thus all parties will know what type of
contract they are entering and whether it is of benefit to them. In addition, the advantage of specific
performance is that market will determine damages and also parties will avoid
litigation costs and errors. On the
other hand, the disadvantage is the risk of inefficiency due to bilateral
monopolies. |