IV. Contracts
E. Breaking contracts
2. The law regarding breach of contract
c. Liability for damages (cont'd.)
Lake River v. Carborundum Co. 769 F.2d 1284 (1985) is a case where a contract provision was held unenforceable because the court viewed it as a penalty rather than reimbursement of actual damages. (F151) It's a Posner decision, well argued with some economic calculations.
Illustrates liquidated damages--damages actually specified in the contract as the money remedy for a breach
"Sometimes a contract will specify the damages to be awarded if there is a breach, ... and if the specification is a reasonable ex ante estimate of the likely damages from breach, it will be enforced under the rubric of liquidated damages even if the actual damages turn out to be much less (or more). But if it is plain from the beginning that the specification is designed to give the victim of the breach much more than he could expect actually to lose as a result of the breach, or the contract breaker to gain, then it is a penalty clause and is unenforceable." (P128)
"A penalty clause is a private version of a property rule." It gives promisee a right that must be bought back. A property rule may be better than a liability rule--avoids courts, expresses confidence in renegotiation options. Yet the same legal system that routinely enforces property rules created by judges and legislatures refuses to enforce property rules privately created by the people they will bind." (F151)Maxton Builders, Inc. v. Lo Galbo, 68 N.Y.2d 373, 502 N.E.2d 184 (1986) is a case upholding liquidated damages where the amount was held reasonable, since the amount (a 10% penalty for breach of a contract to purchase real estate) was close to the underlying economic loss.
If parties to contracts understand the terms that they negotiate, then the court is unlikely to raise welfare with rules that predispose against enforcing the terms.
Overall, there seems to be room for improvement in the efficiency-enhancing impact of court decisions regarding contract damages.
V. Torts
What is a tort? Tort law blends elements of
property, contract, and criminal law
Like property law: your tort rights are good against the world rather
than just a specified bargaining partner
Like contract law: the usual remedy is damages (a liability right)
instead of an injunction (a property right)
Like criminal law:
You have been "wronged" by someone
else
But: tort law is prosecuted privately rather
than by the state
As usual, we want both sides
to behave efficiently in trying to avoid injury
That's the primary economic goal of tort law
Context for now: a situation
in which the injurer does not actually devote resources to making the tort happen
Just may not devote sufficient resources to prevent it from happening
topic areas:
the economics of tort
liability
then the various components
that make up a tort:
harm--is your injury of the type that someone else can be held
responsible for?
causation--can you trace your harm to an action by an injurer?
liability--under what circumstances should the injurer be held
responsible for your harm?
damages--what should you receive for your harm?
finally, we'll consider the special case of intentional torts
none of these topic areas turn out to be as easy as they might seem
A. The economics of tort liability
Our goal for now is to
consider how to encourage efficient behavior by the parties who cause torts and know how
much damage results
So all of the relevant information about the tort is known and
undisputed
So the key focus at this stage is on the economics of liability
Basic analysis
Ex: deciding on how much to invest in safety features for big-rig trucks
3 components:
(1) potential loss (L)
(2) probability of the loss (P)
(3) precautions (s = safeguards)
expected loss
= P(s) x L
cost of safegaurds = C(s)
Benefit of precautions?
Cost of precautions?
efficient level of precaution: MBs = MCs |DP/DS x L| = MCs In words:
Efficiency occurs where the How do we make
the auto company choose the efficient level of precaution? |
![]() |
![]() |
strict liability for damages provides incentives for the injurer to choose the efficient level of precaution
Injurer is liable for any loss
that the injurer is involved in
Strict liability makes the tort system an insurance system
Manufacturers build expected liability costs into the prices of their
products
Those costs include litigation costs, so a pretty expensive insurance
system
[T]ort law is a poor way of
providing insurance. It makes more sense to use insurance companies to provide insurance
and tort law to deter actions that impose costs on others. (F193)