IV. Contracts
A. The economics of contracts
2. Allocating risk (cont'd.)
c. insurance contracts
diminishing marginal utility => risk aversion the extra payment makes it
possible for insurance companies to exist
"Insurance companies ... allocate risk--to themselves, at a
price. (F63)
complications
of insurance contracts
--moral hazard
--adverse selection
(1) moral hazard
insurance-induced reduction of
cost-justified precautions because of
shifting the risks to others
"if an insurer is so careless as to insure a factory for 150
percent of its value, the probability of fire may become very large indeed." (F67)
"If the insurance company is in a better position than the insured
to prevent the loss, transferring it to them via insurance raises efficiency more by
increasing the incentives of the insurance company than it lowers it by reducing the
incentive of the owner. The right rule is to put the incentive where it will do the most
good."(F68)
partial remedy:
coinsurance
moral hazard by insurers also
exists if the expected cost of claim exceeds the policy limit. (P109)
"the law reads into the policy a fiduciary duty of insurer to
insured; that is, the insurer is required to treat the insured as it would treat
itself." (P110)
(2) adverse selection
"an
inefficient outcome due to asymmetric information." (F70)
"The fact that someone wants to buy insurance is evidence that you
should not sell it to him--more precisely, that he is a worse risk than the actuarial
tables imply." (F69)
remedies:
warranty (F71)
universal coverage
(P110)
--but these increase moral hazard
"Such conflicts appear with
disturbing frequency when trying to design efficient legal rules: Fixing one problem often
creates another." (F70-1)
insurance infancy: contracts construed
against the insured. any contributory act excused the insurer. to cut down on moral
hazard, but some insurance is worth accepting moral hazard and insured can't efficiently
control all change in risks (employee behavior, for ex.). As insurance expanded,
conditions relaxed from greater risk pooling. (P109)
Now: Insurance contracts principle: "insurance contracts are to be
construed against the insurer." (P108)
can insured recover from insurer if also paid by injurer? probably not,
since that amplifies income swings due to injuries, contrary to the principle of
insurance. (P108)
you can only insure "something in which you have an insurable
risk." (P109)
avoids imposing costs on a 3rd party:
better health tests can lower welfare by making the risk of bad outcomes uninsurable. It depends on the rule for disclosure, but if the insurance company knows that you have been tested, in advance, then it will not insure you. (the best rule is for the insurance company not to be able to require testing but to be informed about whether a test has occurred--insured can then get tested after buying insurance.) (F72)
IV.
Contracts
B. Making contracts
Goal of efficient contracts: to increase the size of the economic pie, giving a gain to be divided between the parties.
Aspects of contracts that
we'll cover:
making contracts
enforcing contracts
interpreting contracts
breaking contracts
Making contracts -- types of
contracts we'll consider
1. bilateral contracts
2. unilateral contracts
3. implicit contracts
1. Bilateral contracts
express contract
the straightforward case -- 2 parties make an explicit agreement
Minneapolis and St. Louis Railway v. Columbus Rolling Mill 119 U.S. 149 (1886) -- clear offer and acceptance case
--contracts require "offer and acceptance"
Note: parties must mutually
agree to identical terms
A counteroffer
=>
(i) rejection and
(ii) cancellation
of the original offer
Silence can be assent if that is deemed reasonable based on previous dealings (P103)
acceptance is when mailed not when
received
allows earlier preparatory measures. (P103)
Sherwood v. Walker. 66 mich. 568, 33 N.W. 919 (1887)
"mutual mistake" invalidates a contract
remains a controversial decision
? What possible disincentive results from the decision?
? Who had better access to information about the condition of the cow?
? How
would you expect the price of the cow to be affected by the possibility that the cow might
breed?
"there was some evidence that Rose's sale price included her value if
pregnant." => should have been enforced. Possibly so even without evidence
since owner is more likely to be knowledgeable. (P104)
Other examples of mutual mistake:
Baffles v. Wichelhaus 2 H. & C. 906, 159 End. Rep. 375 (Ex, 1864)
-- two ships named Peerless (P104)
Colfax Envelope Corp. v. Local No. 458-33m, 20 F.3d 750 (7th cir. 1994)
-- printing press staffing dispute; contract found to be valid--ambiguous but not a mutual
mistake; Posner opinion (P104)
Hamer v. Sidway 124 N.Y. 538 (1891)
binding contracts require consideration: a benefit for the promisor or a cost for the promisee
consideration moves the promisee to a lower indifference curve detrimental reliance = consideration (F158) courts consider existence, not adequacy of consideration (P101) Suppose the
uncle had promised $5K for turning 21. Enforceable? No |
![]() |
![]() |
"[T]he requirement of
consideration does not exist in property law." (F158)
Perhaps because of other safeguards such as "under the statute of
frauds, all transfers of property must be in writing." (F159)
alternative: base binding contracts on formality to imply that
"we intend this agreement to be enforceable." (F158)
advantage: parties sometimes want simple promises to be
enforceable--ex: donors for college facilities; enforceable promise allows earlier action
summary: a
valid contract requires
(i) offer and acceptance without mutual mistake
-- a "meeting of the minds" and
(ii) consideration