III. Property
C. Exercising property rights (cont'd.)
(5) absolute privileges to use and abuse the land
relatively few restrictions in use under common law
aside from noninterference (externalities) (F110)
"children are difficult to pen" so landowners must fence
dangerous property (P53)
limitations on land use:
Restrictive covenants (F125)
Zoning regulations
Restrictions are inefficient unless they make aggregate property values rise.
(an externality)
(6) absolute powers to transfer in whole or in part (any part carved out by use, space, or time) by sale, gift, descent, or otherwise
transferable =>
"alienable" (LEA190)
alienability may not extend to outsiders, to preserve close-knittedness
(LEA190)
Ex: CA invading NZ
Ex: bequest: feudal/tribal world, law typically specifies
heirs--primogenitre. (CU157)
Ex: mortgage: "The power to mortgage, which is essentially a
conditional promise to transfer, may enable an individual with little capital to acquire
land and help a current landowner to obtain credit." (LEA190)
transfer in part = unbundling
"as long as parties understand what they are purchasing, the law should
generally enforce agreements to unbundled property rights and sell them." (CU164)
land has more rebundling options because "Ownership of land is controlled by an elaborate recording system, involving title deeds, land registries, and the like." (F125)
Sanborn v. McLean 233 Mich. 227 (1925) -- Defendant's deed contained no restrictions nor did the subdivision map. Defendant still could not open a commercial business on his plot. The original owner of the subdivision sold the first set of plots with restrictions against commercial development. Although other plots were later sold without the commercial development restriction, the owners of these plots were held to the restriction because there was a implied negative easement at the time those lots were sold. The defendant had constructive notice of the negative easement because the recorded deeds to other lots in the subdivision contained the restriction. (F126)
Lesson: use rights may be implicitly restricted subject to reasonable search costs.
Rebundling is limited by ability of 3d parties to find out via inspection or record search. (F125)
Rebundling "runs with the
land" only for burdens or benefits which "touch and concern the land" See cases
(F126)
(Example: a fireworod delivery promise would not carry forward)
(P67)
Ex: easement stays with the property. (F124)
Ex: restrictive covenant: (1) generally apply only to the "initial
single ownership of a large area" and (2) are inflexible.
courts tend to enforce covenants if they are reasonable, replacing the
old "touch and concern" rule which may have been too vague to be a useful
"bright line" rule. (F126)
requirements about how obvious covenants must be "in order for it
to be binding on a new owner are stricter for passing burdens than for passing
benefits." Since benefits are more likely to be disclosed voluntarily. See cases (F126)
English common law has "rules against
perpetuities"
Typical limit on perpetuities:
"lives-in-being plus 21 years" (CU158)
It's a generation-skipping rule. Helps curb abuses by foolish heirs. (CU159)
Inalienability:
Rationales:
"Self paternalism may cause us to require certain conditions to exist before we allow a sale of an
entitlement; and it may help to explain many situations of inalienability" (such as
sales while drunk) (LEA197)
True paternalism: based on the notion that others may know better. (LEA197)
Externalities: Bankrupt giving away assets while in bankruptcy proceedings (LEA202)
Moralisms:
Examples: adoptions, blood, human organs (LEA203)
"Many forms of inalienability express conventional morality."
For blood, argument is based on more accuracy of medical history when given away. But
purchases could co-exist, as long as they don't drive out voluntary donations. (CU162)
Body organs. 40K on organ lists; 4,500 Qs per year. Uniform Anatomical
Gift Act in 1968, "makes contracts for the purchase and sale of bodily organs
illegal. Also illegal under the 1994 National Organ Transplant Act, 42 U.S.C. Section 274.
<20% of US driving-age population has filled out cards, but 85% say they "are
willing to make an donation." Could substitute "presumed consent." (CU163)
D. Conflicting property rights
1. Incompatible uses (externalities)
External cost = "nuisance" in law
The market solution: assign property rights & allow bargaining Recall: The problem associated with an externality is jointly
caused--the result of actions by both parties.
Where transaction costs are high, court decisions matter, and cases
suggest at least some general recognition of reciprocal problem and cost/benefit issues.
a. In theory Two decisions for the court:
Common types of rights:
common law remedies: legal or equitable (payment
of compensatory damages vs. injunction) (CU100)
"an injunction . . . is said to "enjoin" the defendant
to do or to refrain from doing a specific act." (CU100)
These rights can be used in combination
Decision 2: Which party to assign the right to?
The party that values the right the
highest
=> place the adjustment burden on the
lowest-cost avoider of damages
Coase principle: minimize the costs of generating highest-valued uses
b. In practice
Alternative approaches to handling incompatible uses - worksheet