Jim Whitney Economics 357

I. Introduction
A. The relationship between law and economics
2. Combining law and economics (cont'd.)

b. Criticisms of the economic analysis of law (cont'd.)

    (2) Efficiency is a deficient assessment criterion
    "repulsive normative underpinnings" (Posner 25)

    (2.1) Income distribution also matters
    "Suppose that pituitary extract is in very scarce supply relative to the demand and is therefore very expensive. A poor family has a child who will be a dwarf if he does not get some of the extract, but the family cannot afford the price and could not even if they borrow against the child’s future earnings as a person of normal height; for the present value of those earnings net of consumption is less than the price of the extract. A rich family has a child who will grow to normal height, but the extract will add a few inches, and his parents decide to buy it for him. In the sense of value used in this book, the pituitary extract is more valuable to the rich than to the poor family because value is measured by willingness to pay, but the extract would confer greater happiness in the hands of the poor family than in the hands of the rich one."
    "As this example shows, the term efficiency when used as in this book to denote those allocations in which value is maximized, has limitations as an ethical criterion of social decisionmaking." (Posner 11)

    Amartya Sen: efficiency itself is not such "a momentous achievement from the point of view of social welfare. A person who starts off ill-endowed may stay poor and deprived even after...[trading] and if being...[efficient]...is all that competition offers, the propertyless may be forgiven for not regarding the achievement as a 'big deal.'" (LEA 27)

    Responses:
    (i) Hard to use the common law to redistribute wealth

    --Litigants are a heterogeneous mix of rich and poor.
    --Unpredictable consequences: "arrangements we try to impose may be bargained away" (ex: tax incidence)
    --"a change in law will alter the distribution of wealth only to the extent that the change is unanticipated and affects the demand for specialized resources." (P 84)
    --Large distortions of incentives: Common law facilitates voluntary transactions, so reactions to legal decisions can work to offset original rule
    --"[I]f property law favors farmers over ranchers, some rich ranchers may switch to farming to gain valuable legal rights. In contrast, a comprehensive income tax precludes people from reducing their tax liability by changing the source of their income." (CU 112)

    (ii) Efficient common law increases the size of the pie available for redistribution


 

    (iii) Better methods for redistribution exist
    24: "An alternative argument for efficient law is that, even when legal rules can be used to redistribute, there are better tools available, such as taxation. If so, it may be sensible to use the legal system to maximixe the size of the pie and leave the legislature and the IRS the job of cutting it."
    Kaplow, Louis, and Steven. "The Efficiency of the Legal System versus the Income Tax in redistributing Income.".Journal of Legal Studies 23 ((June 1994): 667-681.
    --attorney fees vs. accountant fees for income taxes (C&L)

    (2.2) The law concerns justice, not efficiency

    Response: Justice does not have to be incompatible with efficiency
    Economic analysis does not ignore "justice." It does not consider distributive justice, but another type of justice is efficiency. (Posner 27)
    "There is more to justice than economics." (Posner 28)

    --Efficiency considerations can be useful without being determinative
    --Critiquing economic efficiency requires understanding it

    (3) Law provides an alternative to the market, not a complement

    Fundamental critiques handout (summarize each in one sentence)

    Response: Humility
    We are looking only at a part of the law

    --laws which are intended to make markets function better
    --other laws intentionally alter market outcomes--tax laws for example
    --even for those, economists can shed light on trade-offs and side effects
    --but economists can assess only means, not ends

    We may be affected by our perspective
    Some economists have done studies to learn what circumstances promote cooperation among people and what types of people tend to cooperate most. The typical experiment involves setting people up in prisoner's dilemma situations in which, if the affected parties cooperate they maximize their joint product, but each party also has individual incentives to defect or cheat and better him or herself at the expense of the group. Interestingly, it seems that economists are more likely to defect and act on their individual incentives to the detriment of the group than the general population. (Gerald Maxwell & Ruth E. Ames, "Economists Free Ride; Does Anyone Else?" Journal of Public Economics 15 (1981): 295.)
    However, it seems that
this tendency to act on individual incentives is more an identifying feature of people who choose to study economics rather than a characteristic that is learned in the study of economics since underclassmen in economics display the characteristic with almost the same frequency as upperclassmen in economics. (John R. Carter & Michael P. Irons, "Are Economists Different, and If So, Why?" Journal of Economic Perspectives 5 (1991): 171. (LEA 65)


 

c. The benefits of law for economics

    (1) Makes us confront complicated real-world issues.

    In Econ250, firms used resources to produce output--assumed away all the complications

    14: "The more you think about them [property issues], the clearer it becomes that what you own is not a piece of land but a bundle of rights related to a piece of land."

    (2) Challenges economic principles

    "burgeoning literature on how actual human behavior sometimes differs from the predictions of rational choice theory" (much coming from legal academy as well as psychology, econ, other social sciences) (Cooter and Ulen)

        "In the coming years, lawyer-economists will be wise to investigate the benefits of complicating the rational-actor model by admitting two notions: the frailty of human cognition and the possibility of a self-enforced altruism arising from the influence of culture." (LEA 79)


 

B. Review of microeconomic theory (Friedman: explanation)Friedman: explanation)

    Positive vs. Normative
    See handout

1. Maximizing behavior, efficiency and markets

    "maximizing behavior, market equilibrium, and stable preferences, used relentlessly and unflinchingly, form the heart of the economic approach...."
    Becker, Gary S. The Economic Approach to Human Behavior. Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1976, 3-14. Reprinted in O&V: 8-10.

    (1) Individuals act to maximize their welfare

    ? What does a consumer's utility-maximizing optimum look like?

axes.gif (4118 bytes)

 

    (2) A situation is efficient when it is Pareto optimal
    Pareto optimal => it is impossible to make anyone better off without making someone else worse off.

    The Pareto efficiency criterion: a change is welfare-improving if it makes at least one person better off without making anyone else worse off.

    Little would ever get done if policies were implemented only when they are Pareto improving.
    Most changes create both winners and losers.

    Revised criterion in practice

    The Kaldor-Hicks efficiency criterion: a change is welfare-improving if the winners gain more than the losers lose.
    => the change is potentially Pareto-improving

    Focuses on gains versus losses rather than winners and losers.
    Kaldor-Hicks criterion underlies benefit-cost analysis.


 

    (3) Markets typically promote efficiency (Friedman details)

    ? What does a market equilibrium look like?

    Buyer gets a benefit > the price
    Seller receives a price > the cost of inputs
     => Market prices provide incentives for activities that generate positive net benefits (benefits > costs)

    Show: TB, TE, CS
        TR, TC, PS

axes.gif (4118 bytes)