Wednesday, April 25, 2012 |
D.
Macroeconomic shocks and policies
1. Internal shocks
b. Fiscal policy (FP)
Note1: The ER
appreciates more in the SR than in the LR. Exchange
rate overshooting occurs: the tendency of an adjusting ER to initially go beyond its new
long-run equilibrium level.
(Dornbusch--Journal of Political Economy
84(12/76), 1161-1176: predicted before it was observed)
Notice how it occurs becuase NX is less elastic in
the SR than in the LR
Helps explain the excessive variability of ERs and =>
It takes awhile for foreign suppliers to satisfy all of the economy's
credit needs
In the meantime, the currency is overvalued and domestic i-rates are
above i-rates abroad
(speculative bubbles can reinforce overshooting. Example: Appreciating
$. Since ER appreciates beyond its LR level at first, there are profits to be made
initially by banking on its appreciation rather than its subsequent depreciation. This
expectation makes $ a great currency to hold, so speculators bid for it. But the act of
buying $ becomes self-fulfilling. Buying $ in the expectation of $ appr. causes the appr.
Referred to as a bandwagon effect. Can really augment currency swings. The problem is that
the bubble eventually bursts.)
Note2: In the LR, crowding
out of tradables replaces crowding out of investment and can completely
offset the FP stimulus.
(IS shifts all the way back to its original position)
Example: US:
Reaganomics: 1980s versus 1970s:
Budget deficit rose by 2.0% of GDP
CAB fell by 2.3% of GDP.
(shares of GDP, 1971-80 vs 1981-90:
(G-T): 2.2% vs 4.2%. CAB: +0.2% vs -2.1%)
Note: the locomotive effect: foreign sector spreads
FP effects to other countries:
+G --> -NX => +NX*
Example: +Gus = 1% --> +Yus=1.5%, +Ycanada = 0.7%
Overall: floating ERs make MP more powerful but FP less powerful.
Special case: It is possible for NXSR to slope up instead of down. This causes a phenomenon called the "J-curve."
Return to example of expansionary MP
It is still the case that as elasticities rise over time, the situation reverses and the trade balance rises. |
![]() |
What causes a J-curve?
Very inelastic demands for exports and imports
NX$ | = | X$ | - | M$ |
Net trade balance | = Total Revenue from exports (TRx) |
= Total
Expenditure on imports (TEm) |
||
NX$ | = | Pdom · Qx | - | Pfor · QM · ($/fcu) |
Example: suppose Qx and Qm don't change:
depreciation will increase TEm but not TRx, so NX falls instead of rises
How TR and TE change with
price (in this case, R), depends on elasticity.
Recall from Econ101 how price and TR move
in the same direction if demand is inelastic (e<1) and in opposite directions if
demand is elastic (e>1).
The same applies to NX, but we have to consider both TR from
Xs and TE on Ms.
The Marshall-Lerner condition does this:
The Marshall-Lerner condition: A real depreciation raises net exports if and only if | ||||
foreX | + | domeM |
> 1 |
|
foreign elasticity of demand for exports |
domestic elasticity of demand for imports |
=> elastic tradables |
The combined quantity effects must exceed the
price effect
Note: if either elasticity > 1 we're O.K.
Example: For OPEC: can't determine the effect of an ER change by
looking only at the elasticity of demand for OPEC oil. Need to know OPEC elasticity of
demand for imports too. Their short-run demand for our goods rose only a little with their
new-found wealth.
EX: UK: LR elasticities:
eX by ROW = 0.48 and eM by UK = 0.65
eX + eM = 0.48 + 0.65 = 1.13, but lower in short run
See: Devaluation case studies handout
2. Policy making with fixed exchange rates
A fixed ER is a nominal ER that isn't
allowed to move around, outside of a very narrow range called the band.
The government of a
country with fixed ERs pledges to defend the targeted nominal ER (Eo = the
"peg").
Central banks (CBs) must intervene as necessary to prevent
currency appreciation and depreciation
The clue to exchange rate stabilization activity is:
official reserve
transactions (ORT) do not = 0
=> CBs are buying and selling currencies as necessary to try
to maintain targeted values
Who should adopt a fixed ER?
--The whole world has tried in before:
Gold-standard: 1880-1914
Gold-exchange standard: 1945-1973
--Some economists would like to return to global fixed ERs: Laffer and Mundell want a return to gold standard as part of supply side econ.
But most large countries or country blocks
use floating ERs today.
A floating ER gives countries macroeconomic independence
But if it is always best then why not have floating ERs for
states or cities too?
For at least some areas, fixed ERs make more sense
--2 reasons to choose fixed ERs:
(1) You fit into an optimal currency area:
Members are so dependent on each other for transactions that it is too
disruptive to allow daily ER fluctuations
Especially important because I/T take longer than domestic
trans. 3-6 months even for standard Ms and Xs.
Examples: EU / small trade-dependent countries
(2) You suffer from hyperinflation
due to "irresponsible" Central Banks
Example: Argentina -- fixed ER = nominal anchor for the
country's money supply
ER options, per (IMF Annual Report Appendixes) | ||||
Type | 2010 | 2011 | Examples | |
1. | No separate legal tender | 12 | 13 | Ecuador, El Salvador, Panama / European Monetary Union members |
2. | Currency board | 13 | 12 | Hong Kong, Bulgaria |
3. | Fixed pegs and bands | 68 | 66 | Bahrain, Jordan, Saudi Arabia, Nepal / Laos, Jamaica, Pakistan, Vietnam |
4. | Crawling pegs and bands | 7 | 16 | Argentina, China, Egypt, Rwanda |
5. | Other managed arrangement | 21 | 17 | Malaysia, Nigeria, Singapore, Russia |
6. | Floating (managed and independent) | 68 | 66 | Australia, Brazil, Canada, Chile, Colombia, Guatemala, India, Japan, Mexico, Norway, South Africa, Sweden, Turkey, UK, US, EMU (17 members) |
Total | 189 | 190 | => most countries have fixed ERs, but the big ones have floating ERs |
Basic setup
With fixed ERs, traders (CA) and savers
(KA) do not have to compete with each other for FX.
They can behave independently, just turning to Central Banks
to fill gaps in FX availability at the stated rates.
With floating ERs, ERs freely adjust to
clear the CA and KA => ORT = 0
With fixed rates, ERs aren't allowed to clear the CA and KA,
so not surprising when CA and KA get out of balance and CBs have to step in
CBs intervene as necessary to keep E at its peg (Eo)
Ex1: Excess D$ in FX markets => $ appreciation pressure => Fed sells $ and buys FX = expansionary MP --> -r, prevents appreciation easy and cheap to print your own money, but it's inflationary |
Ex2: |
CB intervention for stabilization --> "official reserve transactions" which are fundamentally the same as regular MP
ORT by CBs = MP, but not
autonomous.
CBs must defend E, and MP is the result
Note1: Impossible to fix ER
with all trading partners simultaneously
Fixed only against the peg itself. If
peg appreciates, so do you
Example: Argentina pegging to the $
(2000: <12% of Xs to US)
Note2: The peg is nominal,
not real: R = Eo.Pdom/Pfor
Example:
domestic price inflation can still cause real appreciation
So calling ERs fixed is a bit of misnomer.
The main result is how the commitment affects policy.