February 13, 2012 |
I. The fundamentals of international trade
B. Supply and demand trade geometry
2. Supply and demand
trade geometry for a large country
Dm = the demand for imports
by the buying country
Sx = supply of exports by the selling country
Pa = autarky price
At any given time, only Dm
OR Sx will matter:
Pa foreign < Pa home => draw Dm
Pa foreign > Pa home => draw Sx
To graph an international market:
Step 1: Plot each country's autarky price (Pa) on the vertical axis.
Step 2: Draw Dm for the high-price country and Sx for the
low-price country
Global prices get set in international
markets
Sx and Dm in the international market determine the equilibrium free-trade
price and quantity traded.
Note: Trade tends to equalize prices and costs across countries.
Free-trade price ends up between the
initial autarky prices
When to use the trade market instead instead of the
domestic market:
When working with large countries
What the trade market accomplishes:
Shows where Pf ends up
It will always end up between Pa and Pa'
For any Q
traded, the international market shows how high prices will be in each
country. |
|||||||||||||||
|
Prices get equalized only if the trade volume reaches the international market free-trade equilibrium
Recap:
Note1: Once you find the equilibrium free-trade price, you can carry that back to each domestic market to domestic-market outcomes, such as quantities produced and consumed under free trade.
Note2: Any change in supply or demand conditions in either domestic market spill over into the trade market and change the equilibrium free-trade price and quantity.
Keep in mind:
(1) Domestic autarky prices set the starting points for trade-market Dm
and Sx
(2) Use notation D and S for domestic market and Dm and Sx for trade
market
We use domestic market whenever we can--we see results more
directly. Works just fine for small countries.
We use trade market only in large country cases.
3. Applications of supply and demand trade geometry
Example: Economic sanctions
Economic sanctions aim to impose
pressure on target countries by reducing their gains from trade.
the "sender" country imposes sanctions on the "target"
country
Sanctions are more likely to succeed if
they impose a small cost on the sender and a high cost on the target.
the costs of sanctions rise the more difficult it is to find substitute markets
Suppose the US is considering economic
sanctions--which do
you think would likely be more effective: sanctions on an item we export or an
import we import?
export
sanctions: we are likely to have more market power
Example 1: US movie
exports to Cuba A basic case of an export embargo |
![]() |
Sanctions are more complicated in today's more globalized market
Example 2: Sanctions on oil imports from Iran (worksheet)
Case 1: Iran exports more oil than China demands at the world price
This is shown in the top set of panels in the worksheet.
In the global oil market, add Dm,China onto
Dm to get the total global Dm w/China
and add Sx,Iran onto Sx to get the total global Sx w/Iran
Point f = the free trade equilibrium with
no embargo.
At Pf, Qx,Iran exceeds Qm,China, so Iran depends on the rest
of the world to sell some of its oil. You can see that in both panels.
Point 1 = the embargo equilibrium if all
importers participate.
At point 1, Iran would export nothing and would lose all of
its gains from trade.
Point 2 in the right-hand panel = the embargo equilibrium for the rest of the world if China does not participate.
Point 2 in the left-hand panel = the
embargo equilibrium for China and Iran. Iran can export only to China, so China
gets more oil at a lower price.
China's gains from trade rise by ab
Iran's gains from trade fall by abc.
The embargo hurts Iran but would hurt even more if China were to participate.
Case 2: China demands more oil than Iran exports at the world price
This is shown in the bottom set of panels in the worksheet.
In the global oil market, again add
Dm,China onto Dm to get the total global Dm w/China
and add Sx,Iran onto Sx to get the total global Sx w/Iran
Point f = the free trade equilibrium with
no embargo.
At Pf, Qm,China exceeds Qx,Iran, so even if China were to buy
all of Iran's oil exports at the free-trade price, China would still depend on
the rest of the world for some of its oil imports. You can see that in both
panels.
Point 1 = the embargo equilibrium if all
importers participate.
At point 1, Iran would export nothing and would lose all of
its gains from trade.
Point 2 in the right-hand panel = the
embargo equilibrium if China does not participate. It is the same as the point
f.
The only effect of the embargo is to shuffle suppliers around
so that China buys all of Iran's oil. Iran loses none of its free-trade gains,
and the oil import embargo has no effect.
Which case better reflects
the real world? Here is the info for 2010:
Iran oil exports: 2.5m bbl/day
China oil imports: 6.0m bbl/day
Practice examples not covered in class:
Example 2: Technology and trade
You manage a government's
R&D budget. You have enough funding to finance only one of two competing
innovations: one is for an export industry, the other is for a import-competing
industry. Which would you fund?
Terms of trade:
the price ratios at which a country's exports and imports exchange:
In practice, price indexes are used:
ToT = (Px/Pm)
x 100
Price of what you sell compared to what you buy.
Consider technological change (worksheet)
National welfare is more certain to increase when technological improvements occur in your import industries than in your export industries.
Immiserizing growth: Occurs when higher output makes a
country worse off
--possible for technological change in a country's export
industry
Which innovation would you
be more inclined to share with the ROW?
You get even greater gains if you share technological gains
in your import industries with your trading partners.
Example 3: Multiple trading partners
Draw curves first, then do worksheet
Result: All gains from trade go somewhere specific