E.
Breach of contract
2. The law
regarding breach of contract
c. Liability
for damages (cont'd.)
Per Oliver Wendell Holmes:
"The duty to keep a contract at common law means a prediction that you must pay
damages if you do not keep it--and nothing else."
Oliver Wendell Holmes, The Path of the Law, 10 Harv. L. Rev. 457, 462
(1897)(P119n)
Liability for damages resulting from breach of contract handout
Both cases illustrate an
efficient breach of contract
In both cases cost and market value of performance differed
from each other
substantially at the time of the breach
The cases conflict with each other in other key respects
Posner
criticizes the size of the award in Groves
The entire gain from the breach was awarded to Groves
Makes the defendant (assuming he had anticipated the result)
indifferent between breaching and (inefficiently) performing. (F162-3)
My
criticism is with the Peevyhouse award
Compared to Groves, Peevyhouse presents a stronger case for
cost of performance damages due to the greater role of subjective valuation and
the smaller role of unforeseen events.
(the dissent in Groves expressed support for cost of performance for "personal"
use; court in Peevyhouse said it would also apply here if the contract had been
specifically for improvements)
The court decision opens a can
of worms regarding efficiency, freedom of contract, and opportunism
Damages set equal to the cost of performance puts both parties closest to where
they expected to end up based on expectations at the time of the contract
Avoids incentives for opportunistic behavior ex post.
Smaller damages risk confounding and therefore discouraging
contracts
Per Posner, damages = cost of performance discourages efficient breach
by making the promisor indifferent between performing and breaching even when a
breach is efficient
However, the promisee retains the option of renegotiating
to let the promisor out of a contract, and can gain from bargaining when it is
inefficient to complete a contract.
specific performance might offer similar efficiency advantages
Hadley
v Baxendale, 9 Ex. 341 (1854) [case illustrates that liability is limited to what damages can in general be
anticipated, not special damages such as lost profits, unless specifically warned of
special circumstances]
plaintiff = millers; defendant = carriers
Court ordered a new trial with explicit instructions that damages not include the foregone profits, since it was not reasonable to expect the defendant to consider them unless they had been specifically mentioned by the plaintiff.
The case is British but is universally accepted in Anglo-Saxon common law
Illustrates
consequential damages, which are
not
traditionally awarded under the common law
"The general principle is that if a risk of loss is known
to only one party to the contract, the other party is not liable for the loss if it
occurs." (P127)
What incentive does this create during the contracting process?
Promotes disclosure of information
Example: the film from a trip
to the Himalayas
Request special handling, but then expect to pay extra for the extra
care
But note that it does result in an asymmetry:
Without specific disclosure, damages are capped by average
circumstances, but there is no floor to damages, so contract damage payments have a
downward bias.
V. Torts
What is a tort? Tort law blends
elements of property, contract, and criminal law
Like property law: your tort rights are good against the
world rather than just a specified bargaining partner
Like contract law: the usual remedy is damages (a liability
right) instead of an injunction (a property right)
Like criminal law:
You have been "wronged" by
someone else
But: tort law is prosecuted privately
rather than by the state
As usual, we want
both sides to behave efficiently in trying to avoid injury
That's the primary economic goal of tort law
Context for now: a
situation in which the injurer does not actually devote resources to making the
tort happen
Just may not devote sufficient resources to prevent it from
happening
topic areas:
the economics of tort
liability
then the various
components that make up a tort:
harm--is your injury of the type that someone else can be
held responsible for?
causation--can you trace your harm to an action by an
injurer?
liability--under what circumstances should the injurer be
held responsible for your harm?
damages--what should you receive for your harm?
A. The economics of tort liability
Our goal for now is
to consider how to encourage efficient behavior by the parties who cause torts
and know how much damage results
So all of the relevant information about the tort is known
and undisputed
So the key focus at this stage is on the economics of
liability
Basic analysis
Ex: deciding on how much to invest in safety features for big-rig trucks
3
components:
(1) potential loss (L)
(2) probability of the loss (Pr)
(3) precautions (s = safeguards)
expected loss = Pr(s) x L
cost of safeguards = C(s)
Benefit of precautions?
Cost of precautions?
efficient level of precaution: MBs = MCs
|dPr/dS
x L| = MCs
In words: Efficiency occurs where the
How do we make the auto company choose the efficient level of precaution? |
![]() |
![]() |
strict liability for damages provides incentives for the injurer to choose the efficient level of precaution
Injurer is liable
for any loss that the injurer is involved in
Strict liability makes the tort system an insurance system
Manufacturers build expected liability costs into the prices
of their products
Those costs include litigation costs, so a pretty expensive
insurance system
Complication 1: moral hazard
With strict liability for damages, how does a potential victim feel about being injured compared to not being injured?
So how careful will a potential victim be?
strict liability for damages provides no incentive for potential victims to take
precautions
if victim
precaution is not feasible, then strict precaution is efficient
How
do we make car owners choose the efficient level of victim precaution?
i.e., make them internalize the expected harm to themselves
no liability for damages provides incentives for the victim to choose the efficient level of precaution
So how can people
get compensated for their losses?
Insurance contracts: we do that for many related purposes
now: auto insurance, homeowners' insurance, life insurance, disability insurance
If you suffer a loss, it doesn't matter whether someone
wronged you or not--you are still worse off than before
Insurance offsets at least part of the loss
result is a contradiction: with no liability, the injurer will not take any precautions
How do we get both sides to take precautions?
negligence = failure to take all cost-justified precautions negligence rule: an injurer is liable only if negligent result: |
![]() |
![]() |