IV.
Contracts
C. Enforcing contracts (cont'd.)
fraud =
deception
Hidden in fine print on page three of your auto rental contract:
"I agree to give everything I own to Hertz?"
Contracts so complicated
that consumers don't really know what they are signing.
Fraudulent contracts are not enforceable between the contracting parties
2 potential types of fraud involving information:
Type 1: providing false information--always a fraud
Ex: Harding
v. Ja Laur Corp.
related fraud cases:
Love
v. Elliott, 350 So. 2d 93 (Fla. App. 1977): Russell fraudulently got Mrs.
Elliott, who was illiterate, to sign by her mark a deed conveying a much larger mineral
interest in her property than she had agreed to sell. Russell then recorded his deed and
sold his interest. The buyer was held to have good title, the court holding that a deed
procured by fraud, unlike a forged deed, could be used to pass title to a bona fide
purchaser.
Cumberland
Capital Corp. v. Robinette, 331 So. 2d 709 (Ala. App. 1976) On the other hand
held that a signature procured by deceiving the grantor about what he was signing counted
as a forgery.
"The liar makes a positive investment in manufacturing and
disseminating false information."
"forbidding sellers to lie...save[s] the expense of the
self-protective measures that buyers would have to take." (P111)
Lying is "unlawful even if the buyer could unmask the lie at
very low cost." (P113)
market remedies exist: trade associations to correct individual seller
misinformation; department stores to "inform consumers about the merits of particular
goods." Problem with trade associations: free riding; no producer has an incentive to
disclose negative info that pertains to all sellers; industries may be monopolies. (P112)
"If one cigarette manufacturer advertises that smoking is good for
your health, other cigarette manufacturers will have no incentive to disparage the
claim." [counterexample: Ford and seatbelts] (P112)
Type 2: withholding useful information--not usually a fraud
case
for disclosure: reduces information costs
Stambovsky v. Ackley: "We do
not want a system in which people who happen to have information highly relevant to the
value of what they are selling... have an incentive to withhold it...." (F170)
"The case for requiring disclosure is strongest when a
product characteristic is not ascertainable by the consumer at low cost." infrequent
purchases; not discernable; expensive. (P113)
Ex: some courts consider it a fraud to not disclose termite
infestations (P111)
Competitive market
response to high information costs: Warranties: "a guaranty of results...makes
the disclosure of information unnecessary." (P113)
case against
disclosure:
protects
the value of acquiring information that can be costly and useful
Ex: Laidlaw
(d,app,seller) v Organ (p,buyer), 15 U.S. 178 (1817).
Organ received advance news about the Treaty of Ghent ending of the War
of 1812 and bought tobacco in anticipation of end of blockade of New Orleans. Laidlaw
tried to back out of tobacco contract. LA Supreme Ct said no. (P110)
The argument for the court's position: Getting information is not free,
and Organ's transaction helped move market toward new equilibrium.
(P111)
"If the Louisiana
Supreme Court had ruled in favor of Laidlaw rather than Organ, and consistently followed
the same rule in other cases, the result would have been less speculation and more
unstable prices for agricultural commodities." (F170)
Offset: Organ's victory
induces rent seeking. (F169)
There is no direct link between private and social benefit from
information
Anthony T.
Kronman, "Mistake, Disclosure, Information, and the Law of Contracts, 7 J. Leg. Stud.
1, 9-18 (1978).
Summary:
Fraud does not usually include failure to disclose information
Efficiency => protect value-promoting information (Laidlaw
v. Organ) but not
wealth-shifting information (Stambovsky v. Ackley)
Note regarding Stambovsky v. Ackley: Courts do not usually
second-guess the subjective valuations of contracting parties.
The fact that no
'rational' person would pay less for for the properties on account of these facts was
irrelevant; the courts accepted the 'subjectivity' of values, a cornerstone of freedom of
contract and modern economic theory. P265
Ex: sanitarium covered under property
b. situational monopoly
exercise of ordinary monopoly
power does not void a contract
but abuse of monopoly circumstances linked to the bargaining situation
can
Alaska Packers Assn. (p) v. Domenico (d,app), 117 F. 99 (1902)
Notes re Alaska Packers:
Famous case
related case: Austin Instrument Inc. v. Loral Corp., 29 N.Y.2d 124, 272 N.E.2d 253 (1971): a firm obtained refund of a price increase, which it had agreed to pay under pressure, on grounds of economic duress. The "emergency" was the result of the supplier threatening to breach its contract if it did not get the higher price.
Related
situation:
Necessity: dire straits, but not caused by the conduct of your contract
partner
Ex: saving a sinking ship
(bilateral monopoly)
Efficiency =>
Charge ship owners the expected cost of rescue
Pay the rescuer the value of the cargo (F154-5)
--insurance schemes can do this
the present legal rule "permits an admiralty court to rewrite a
contract that is too favorable to one side." Lowers chance of sinking while
bargaining. (F156)
Posner gets this
wrong--worries about "excessive" efforts when the efforts to rescue due to
getting the full value are efficient. This is not like the patent race or the sunk
treasure case, because if another rescuer is expected in ten minutes, the first one isn't
going to be able to get a very high price. (F)
Seemingly
related to duress: form contracts
contracts of adhesion - "take
it or leave it contracts"
Consumers retain choice between competing suppliers
Form contracts reduce
drafting costs, eliminate the problem of the firm having to control the employee who
negotiates the individual contracts.
The argument for freedom of
contract holds in this case since the firm, in drafting the contract, will take account of
benefits and losses to its customers. Anything that makes the terms of the deal more
attractive to the customer will also increase the amount he is willing to pay.
Even for a monopolist: The more unfavorable the contract is to the
consumer, the lower the price the monopolist will be able to charge. Customers still have
the alternative of not buying the good.
Courts sometimes refuse to enforce the terms of form contracts on the
grounds that they represent a sort of duress. These arguments suggest the courts are
wrong.
Williams (d,app) v. Walker-Thomas Furniture Co. (p), 350 E2d 445 (1965)
Contracts with unconscionable terms are not enforceable
Unconscionable => an absence of meaningful choice on the part of one of the parties together with contract terms which are unreasonably favorable to the other party. it's another case of "unequal bargaining power" but not in the context of temporary circumstances => it should be possible to shop around for a better deal related case: Weaver v. American Oil Co., 257 Ind. 458, 276 N.E.2d 144 (1971) a contract was found unenforceable in part on the basis of unequal bargaining power Controversial:
D. Interpreting contracts
Progress so far: Concern now:
The parties have a dispute about the details of the contract and turn
to the court to resolve a dispute about its interpretation
Fundamental question: Why not just enforce the contract as it is written?
Presumption: freedom of contract --> Pareto improving exchange
--efficient contract terms create the largest potential gain for the
contracting parties to divide up, so that's what we would expect the parties to achieve
--the contract price should be tailored to the contract's
terms--regarding quality of performance, allocation of risks, etc.
Sources of litigation regarding
interpretation of contracts:
1. filling gaps in contracts -- some relevant clauses is omitted
2. interpreting and modifying contract language -- some included clause
is misspecified
Should
efficiency or intentions govern how the court interprets contracts?
--Ordinarily,
intentions, since parties likely knew what they wanted better than the courts do. (P96)
--Court interference with intentions will make parties write longer
contracts, which is costly. (F)
1. filling gaps in contracts
There is never enough fine print to
cover all aspects of a bargain, so we need some rules for filling in the gaps
Parties omit clauses if cost of contracting exceeds benefits
This gives a role for the court in
contract disputes:
filling out the parties' agreement by interpolating missing clauses.
(P96)
goal of courts is to try to fill in
terms the parties would have come up with (F160)
--efficient; and
--cuts contract costs since parties know that court will promote a
mutually beneficial back-up role
(1) Implicit understandings Wood (p) v. Duff-Gordon (d), 222 N.E. 88 (1917) "contract for an exclusive dealership contains an implied condition that the dealer shall use his best efforts to sell the supplier's product." -- good example of implied terms; designer (P95n4) P=agent/distributor; D=creator of fashions
(2) unspecified adversities (P96)
--allocation of risk
Suydam
(p,landlord)
v. Jacskon (d,tenant,app) 54 N.Y. 450 (1873)
illustrates initial rental agreements, with tenants liable
Under common law, tenants bore implicit liability for unspecified adversities
Greenfield
(p,lessor) v. Kolea (d,app,lessee) 475 Pa. 351 (1977)
-- in this case, the appellant is listed second; the order remains the same as
at the trial court level
Does the lease
agreement specify whether rent is owed if premises become uninhabitable?
no
2 options for allocating risk:
(i) specify in contract
(ii) let court determine intent