Jim Whitney Economics 495

III. Contracts

    Property: elaborated the notion of ownership that we glossed over in micro theory
    Enriched our perception

    Contract: we must revise the fundamental context we used in micro theory
    With contracts, we do not operate in an environment of perfect competition.
    At the outset, we can shop for a competitive contract, but once we enter into a contractual relationship, the environment is one-on-one.
    It's not a situation we dealt with in micro theory

    As usual, general purpose: to assess and promote the efficiency of contracts and contract law

    topic areas:
    the economics of contract
    making contracts--does a contract exist?
    enforcing contracts--does the contract deserve to be enforced?
    interpreting contracts--what are its terms; how should missing terms be inferred?
    breaking contracts--what should be done when someone breaches a contract?


 

    A. The economics of contracts

    Why do people make enforceable contracts?
    Why not do everything on the spot market?

    Some transactions take time

    Recall with property: assigning rights affects distribution of wealth => can use property law for goals other than efficiency
    Contract law: "concerned with facilitating the voluntary movement of property rights into the hands of those who value them most" (P31)
    Redistribution is much less feasible with contracts: Contracts are a "setting of low transaction costs, and therefore a judicial failure to discover the efficient solution can be retified in the future through a drafting change." So "contract law cannot readily be used to achieve goals other than efficiency." (P98)

    Purposes of contracts:
    --Aligning incentives
    --Allocating risk


 

    1. Aligning incentives

    a. The bilateral monopoly problem

    Ex: I take you up to Alaska on my boat to help me harvest salmon.
    We get to our remote fishing location and proceed to work out the wage

    Bilateral monopoly = monopoly seller facing a monopsony buyer
    Arises once a transaction between 2 parties begins
    Per Posner: opportunism (P93,95)

    (1) = monopoly seller's surplus-maximizing optimum
    (2) = monopsony buyer's surplus-maxmimzing optimum

axes.gif (4118 bytes)
whitespace.gif (816 bytes)

    Result: inefficient and incompatible incentives

    Remedy? Make an enforceable contract ex ante


 

    b. The principal-agent problem

    relational contract: one party (the principal) delegates actions to another (the agent)
    common agents in contracts: lawyers, accountants, brokers, trustees
    the problem: incompatible incentives--maximize welfare subject to contract constraints

    game theory ((F,ch.8)  Price theory coverage and explanation of solution concepts.)

    Ex: Investor-broker:  i = 4%
    investment: $100 in Yr0 --> $112 in Yr1
    $2 for the broker / $10 for the investor

    Case 1: No enforceable contract:

    Broker (agent, promisor)
a. Perform b. Breach
Investor
(principal
promisee)
1. Don't invest a1 \   0
\
4  \
b1 \   0
\
4  \
2. Invest a2   \    2
\
10 \
b2        \ 100
    \
-100 \

    Outcome: Row 1--don't invest


 

    Case 2: Enforceable contract--guarantee returns:
    Agent has a fiduciary duty: must treat the principal as an alter ego.
(P114)

    Broker
a. Perform b. Breach
Investor 1. Don't invest a1 \   0
\
4  \
b1 \   0
\
4  \
2. Invest a2   \    2
\
10 \
b2        \ -10
    \
10 \

 

    Outcome: Cell a2--invest + perform


 

    So who gains from enforceable contracts?   Both parties

    Why might the promisor perform even without enforceable contracts?

    reputation: "may be the most important method for enforcing agreements in our society, although not the one of most interest to lawyers." (F145)
    -- works well when "the amounts at stake are small, the issues simple, and the parties are engaged in repeat dealings." (F145)
    Ex: "Trusted private arbitrators": Diamond industry in NY, "dominated by orthodox Jews, forbidden by their religious beliefs from suing each other." The trustworthy rabbi mitigated disputes. Helps explain why "particular trades are sometimes dominated by a single close-knit ethnic group." (F146)
    "commercial arbitrator": each party "posts a bond with [a] third party ... we both trust." the 3rd party arbitrates. (F147)

    has the advantage of providing market incentives to judge correctly (good arbitrators get rehired)

    reputation incentive: "someone known not to perform his side of bargins will find it difficult to find anyone willing to make exchanges with him in the future...."
    but... in some contexts, reputation does not work.
    It is dependent on reliable information about who was in the wrong
    The promisor might be old; the contract could be very large; or s/ he can function w/o contracts in the future. (P94)

    Ex: long-term guaranteed contracts in sports

    Result: welfare-improving bargains fail to occur w/o enforceable contracts
    Ex: "E may be willing to guarantee the superior durability of his shirt, but, if his promise is not legally enforceable, consumers may doubt the honesty of his claim" (P94)

    The fundamental function of contract law (and recognized as such at least since Hobbes' day) is to deter contracting parties from behaving opportunistically, in order to encourage the optimal timing of economic activity and (the same point) obviate costly self-protective measures." (P94)
    opportunism is not always obvious--paint a self-portrait "to customer's satisfaction." Court will not enforce payment, since terms implied customer satisfaction was necessary. (P95)

    "Good-faith performance--which means in this context not trying to take advantage of the vulnerabilities created by the sequential character of contractual performance--is an implied term of every contract." (P95)


 

    2. Allocating risk

    We live in a world of uncertainty (Ref: Friedman, Price Theory, choice under uncertainty (F64))
    Some risks are out of our control: fires, floods, earthquakes
    For many risks, we can mitigate damages: nonflammable roof shingles, raised foundations, bolted foundations
    But we also assume many risks: build homes in forests, on hillsides, near earthquake faults

    Contracts are affected by unforeseen contingencies (P)
    Who should bear the risk if something goes wrong?

    "Legal rules allocate risk." (F63)

    2 methods for minimizing loss in contracts (P105)
    prevention
    insurance

    "Insurance is one way of dealing with unforeseen contingencies, and contracts are often a method of insurance." (P97)

    prevention and insurance overlap in practice, so we need to cover our attitudes for risk before proceeding

    Risk aversion =>
    (i) people pay more for a contract that allows them to transfer risk
    (ii) people buy insurance contracts that pool risks

    insurance pools risk and thereby eliminates it (by the law of large numbers)
    "Transferring risk does not eliminate it, but pooling risk does." (F64)

 


 

    "one simple rule for allocating risks: Put the incentive where it does the most good." (F72)
    some losses are preventable, so assigning risk efficiently can increase prevention

    (1) explicit contract

    Ex: "extended service contract" -- shifts risk to the party which can avoid it more cheaply. (F69)

    (2) implicit contract

    Ex: Why have companies like Coca-Cola switched from glass to plastic for soda bottles?

    --a Coca-Cola bottle blows up? (F69)

    Ex1: implied warranty against hazards: provides an incentive for Coca Cola to provide safe packaging
    preventable loss -- cost-effective to avoid
    Coke switched to plastic bottles

    --Who absorbs costs if a product doesn't work as advertised?
    a carpet shampoo that can't clean your particularly dirty carpet

    Ex2: implied warranty of fitness for intended use: seller is cheaper insurer since seller can pool risks that a defect occurs, so can charge more for the product by accepting the risk. (P106)

    --Who is responsible if a partially completed custom-ordered house burns down?

    Ex3: fixed-price contract: "Ordinarily, a fixed-price contract is intended to assign to the performing party the risk of problems encountered in performance." (P107)
    Ex: cost of materials for Oxy residence hall

    "The manufacturer warrants those and only those dimensions of performance that are primarily within his control rather than the buyer's." Ex: fire at warehouse before delivery. (P97)
    WI hired Bentley to build wings for capital. sued when they collapsed. state lost since bentley had followed architect plans, and plans were faulty. state could have prevented loss more cheaply by more careful selection of architect. 97n: bentley v. state. 73 Wis. 416, 41 N.W. 338 (1889) (P97)


 

    impossibility:

    Who pays to rebuild a partially completed custom-ordered house that gets destroyed by earthquake?
    ex1: oil companies found liable for losses due to oil undelivered because of the outbreak of war in the Middle East

    ex2: difficult soil is no excuse for breaking a water drilling contract; blight is an excuse for failing to deliver contracts to a grain elevator (though futures contracts may change the picture). (P107)
    "If the promisor is the cheaper insurer, the fact that he could not have prevented the event that prevented him from performing should not discharge him." (P106)

    force majeure ("greater force") clause: specifies the circumstances in which failure to perform will be excused. (P107)

    --promisor dies partway through a personal services contract?
    discharge is normally allowed for personal service contracts in event of death, unless the promisor could have reasonably foreseen it.
(P107)