Jim Whitney Economics 311

The J-Curve

Example: Country: U.S. Germany
Currency: Dollar ($) Euro (eu)
Output Budweiser (bud) St. Pauli Girl (spg)
whitespace.gif (816 bytes)
    May June and after
1.  Exchange rate (E) 1.5 Eu per $ 0.75 eu per $
2.  Price of U.S. beer (Pbud) $3 (6 eu) $3 (3 eu)
3.  Price of German beer (Pspg) 4.5 eu ($3) 4.5 eu ($6)
           
      June Sept. Dec.
4.  Quantity exported (Qx) 6 8 8 8
5.  Export receipts (X) = Pbud.Qx  $3.6 = $18      
           
6.  Quantity imported (Qm) 6 6 4 2
7.  Import payments (M) = Pspg($).Qm   $3.6 = $18      
8.  Net exports (X-M)  $18-$18=$0      
whitespace.gif (816 bytes)
      Ordinarily, when our real exchange rate depreciates, we would expect our trade balance to rise since the depreciation has enhanced our competitiveness, lowering domestic product prices relative to foreign prices. However, the trade balance doesn't always rise, especially not right away. The paradox of a deteriorating current account in the face of enhanced competitiveness is resolved by the Marshall-Lerner stability condition.
      The possibility of a J-curve arises because each one percent depreciation of a currency makes a country's initial volume of imports one percent more expensive. The country's net exports can rise only if changes in trade volumes can offset this price effect.
    Formally, a depreciation raises net exports if and only if:
the % increase in
quantity exported
+ the % decrease in
quantity imported
> the %
depreciation
    Divide both sides by the % depreciation:
the % increase in
quantity exported
the % depreciation
+ the % decrease in
quantity imported
the % depreciation
> 1.
The numerators are percentage changes in quantities and the denominator is the percentage change in foreign exchange prices, so the two lefthand terms are elasticities: the first term is the foreign elasticity of demand for domestic exports and the second is the domestic elasticity of demand for imports. The Marshall-Lerner condition states that the two elasticities must add up to a value greater than one:
(*) foreign elasticity
of demand for
domestic exports (eX*)
+ domestic elasticity
of demand for
imports (eM)
> 1.
In other words, the combined quantity effects must offset the price effect of the depreciation.
      Consider the intuition behind (*): The righthand side of (*) says that each 1% depreciation raises the dollar cost of current import volume by 1%. The lefthand side of (*) says that the larger quantity of exports and smaller quantity of imports must add up to more than a 1% improvement to overcome the adverse price effect.
whitespace.gif (816 bytes)