Monday, February 04, 2013 |
II. Consumer demand
A. The rational consumer
1. The budget constraint
A useful
special case BL:
X = a product of interest
Y = Ig = $ of income spent on all goods other than X
How
it looks: I = Px X + Ig => Example1: Ig = 60 - 3X ? What does the vertical
intercept tell us in this case? Graph a point "a" Example2: Homework 4 |
|
? How much income are you
spending on goods OTHER than X?
? And how much income are you
spending on X (TEx)
You can read TEx directly from the vertical axis:
Whatever income isn't spent on other goods is spent on X
For any value of X, TEX = I - Ig
In other words, how far you've moved down your BL to
reach your consumption of good X tells you how much income you've used up to buy it, and
that's your total expenditure on X (TEx).
Real world applications (Java)
2. Consumer preferences and indifference curves (Uo)
We've set up the consumer's constraints which
establish consumption possibilities
Now we turn to preferences to see what choices the consumer will make
Learning objectives: Diagram and interpret the consumer's indifference curve. Explain the meaning, geometry and formula for the marginal rate of substitution (MRS).
a. Basic concepts
Focus is on pure consumption: use it or lose it, but you have free disposability (you can throw away but not sell what you don't consume)
For any bundles A and B, a consumer
is able to decide:
"I prefer A to B."
"I prefer B to A."
"I am indifferent between A and B."
Consumer preferences are: (1) complete, (2) stable, and (3) transitive (A>B and B>C = A>C)
Concept related to total utility: Marginal Utility (MU): the
increase in total utility due to the consumption of one extra unit of some item, holding
all else constant:
MUx = DU/DX
MUy = DU/DY
Example: You consume donuts (D) and
milk (M).
Milk consumption rises with your quantity of donuts fixed
Property (1) of utility: the MU of any economic good is positive.
MUi = dU/di > 0 for any good i. (more is better)
Property (2) of utility: MU falls as
consumption rises
("law of diminishing marginal utility)."
dMUi/di = d2U/di2 < 0 for any good i.
As with the budget line for consumer constraints, to illustrate consumer decision-making for more than one item, we need to be able to incorporate consumer utility into our x-y diagram. That's our next step.
b. Geometry
Indifference curves: Arise when
consumers face a choice and respond, "I don't care which I choose."
Indifference curve:
a set of consumption bundles that a consumer regards as equally desirable.
Example: milk and donuts. Along the indifference curve, U(M,D) = Uo, where Uo is a constant. ? Where in the diagram are
consumption bundles that you would not like as much as the bundles along Uo? Indifference map: a set of several indifference curves. |
![]() |
Utility
is a consumer's genuine "real income"
=> all along Uo, real income is constant.
(The consumer is equally happy even though the consumption bundles and
their money costs differ.)
Examples of indifference
curves:
Worksheet
Think each case through and don't be surprised if these curves have
rather unusual shapes compared to the
'typical' curves we covered in the basic geometry.
Illustrations of worksheet examples
(Java)